8.1 INTRODUCTION
Thus far we
have been considering, under conveniently simplified assumptions, the location
of individual units and also the location patterns of classes of similar units,
or activities. It is now time to advance from such basic location theory into
the domain of regional economics by focusing on two extremely important
kinds of complexes of locational units and activities: the urban place and the region. This chapter deals with urban places and the next
chapter with regions.
Some
intimations of why and how cities1 come into being
have already emerged in the course of our inquiries into locational principles.
In Chapter 3, reference was made to the special
transfer advantages of large junctions and terminals, including intermodal
transshipment points. In Chapter 5, we found that
some types of activities favor a highly clustered pattern, in which certain
external economies of agglomeration can be secured.
Thus if we
define an urban place as a spatial concentration involving a variety of
activities, we can already see some good economic reasons for the existence of
such concentrations. The present chapter is addressed to questions of the size,
spacing, and functional type of urban places. Here we shall be treating each
such place as a single location.
There are
two different (and basically complementary) approaches to an understanding of
the location of cities. The first is historical: It asks why specific cities
arose where they did, and why certain cities grew and others did not in a
particular historical context.2 From this
kind of case study we learn much about the diverse origins of individual
cities. We find that for some, the decisive initial advantage of the site was
its security against armed attack; for others, a good natural harbor convenient
to a productive hinterland; for others, an easy place to cross a wide river or
a mountain range; for still others, a pleasant climate or other
amenities.
However, we
also find that in many cases the original reason is no longer the principal
basis of continued growth, and that once a city reaches substantial size it
develops important economies of agglomeration that encourage still further
growth.3 As Wilbur Thompson puts it, in his
exposition of the urban size ratchet,
If the growth of
an urban area persists long enough to raise the area to some critical size (a
quarter of a million population?) structural characteristics, such as
industrial diversification, political power, huge fixed investments, a rich
local market, and a steady supply of industrial leadership may almost ensure
its continued growth.4
The
structural characteristics identified by Thompson are certainly important for
the growth of an area. But the use of the term "ratchet" perhaps goes too far
in implying that there is something irreversible about growth beyond the
critical size. As we shall see later in this chapter, plenty of exceptions
appear in recent data.
The
complementary approach seeks to explain not individual cities and their
peculiarities, but spatial distributions of cities as related to size
and function. In developing a theory of "systems of cities," we first assume
away all the special advantages of particular sites and imagine a uniform
landscapewith all inputs equally available everywhere, demand for outputs
evenly distributed, and transfer costs uniform in all directions, On such a
tabula rasa, would economic forces give rise to some orderly pattern of urban
concentrations? If so, what would it look like? The basic principles of
urbanization patterns, disclosed by this kind of highly simplified analysis,
can then be appropriately developed and modified to provide some useful
insights about the real world. This is the approach pioneered by Walter
Christaller and August Lösch and subsequently developed by many economists
and geographers, notably Brian Berry.5 It is
often called central-place theory.
8.2
THE FORMATION OF A SYSTEM OF CITIES
8.2.1
Some Simplifying Assumptions
In order to
highlight the basic factors that give rise to spatial patterns of cities, we
shall start with the highly simplified central-place model conceived by
Christaller and Lösch. There are only two activities in this model: one
rural and one urban. The rural activity is an extensive land user, such as
agriculture, having no significant economies of agglomeration. The urban
activity is subject to substantial agglomeration economies (internal, external,
or both), but it can use land intensively and requires a relatively
insignificant amount of space. People engaged in each of the two activities
require the output of the other activity.6 All land is of uniform quality, and transfer costs are proportional
to straight-line distance in any direction. The extensive rural activity, and
consequently the demand for the output of the urban activity, is uniformly
distributed.
It will be
noted that in this rudimentary economic system, there are only two location
factors: transfer costs and agglomeration economies.
8.2.2
Shapes of Trading Areas
As we found
in Chapter 4, a single seller located somewhere
in a limitless plain uniformly seeded with customers would serve a circular
market area, its radius being basically limited by transfer costs on the goods
sold.7 Such a situation is represented in Figure 8-1. Panel (a) of that figure shows a seller
with the spatial demand curve Ds. The seller has established
the f.o.b. price of p0and produces at the rate of output q0, which is given by the intersection of marginal revenue (MRs) and marginal cost (MC) .The sellers
average total costs of production are represented by the curve ATC. Panel (b) is simply a map showing the sellers location at point A and its circular market area.
But if we
now envisage the urban activity being taken up in more locations, the market
areas of the various sellers will impinge on one another. Thus in panel (a) of Figure 8-2, we find that a new seller located at C has cut into the market area of the seller at A by drawing away
customers in the shaded area. Because the original seller at A now has
fewer customers, its demand curve will shift leftward, forcing it to establish
a lower f.o.b. price and reducing its profits. The decrease in demand is shown
in panel (b) of Figure 8-2 as the shift from Ds, to Ds.. For simplicity the marginal cost curve and the
marginal revenue curves associated with the spatial demand curves have been
omitted in Figure 8-2.)
As long as
there are opportunities for profitable establishment of more production
centers, these areas will become more numerous. Eventually, as new sellers
crowd into the market, the demand curve of each seller will have shifted to a
position shown by D"sin panel (b) of Figure 8-2, where it is tangent to the sellers
average total cost curve, ATC. The market areas are now so compressed
that all excess or economic profits are eliminated. Each seller earns normal
profits, just sufficient to keep it in business, and there is no incentive for
any more sellers to enter the market.
What will
this "equilibrium" pattern of centers and trade areas look like? If all parts
of the market are served from one center or another, if all the centers have
equal locational advantages, and if the transfer surface is uniform, the areas
must be identical polygons bounded by straight linesas was stated in Chapter 4. Only three symmetrical and uniform
shapes of market area will fill the surface under these conditions: squares,
hexagons, and equilateral triangles. Of these, the hexagon is the "most
efficient" in the sense that it gives the smallest average distance between
sellers and buyers.8 A honeycomb is a good
example of how initially circular areas (cells) become hexagonal when pressure
squeezes them into a shape that will utilize all the available space.
But in many
cases the transport grid is basically rectilinearas in most modern
urban street patterns and over a major part of the rural area of the United
States, where the land surveys were made in terms of a checkerboard of square
townships and sections and where most local roads have followed section and
township boundaries. Under such conditions, market-area boundaries and the
trading areas of towns tend to be not hexagonal or triangular but
square.
8.2.3 A
Hierarchy of Trading Areas
Next, we
shall take a more realistic approach by recognizing more than just a single
urban activity. The size of the trade area for a specific product depends on
(1) the nature of the spatial demand curve and (2) cost or supply
considerations. From our discussion of the spatial demand curve and pricing in
Chapter 4, we can isolate transfer costs (per ton-mile) and market
density (per square mile) as the crucial demand factors determining the
size of trading areas. On the supply side, the extent of scale or other
agglomeration economies (as shown by the ATC curve) are most
important. Obviously, each of these conditions varies from one activity to
another. Accordingly, we might expect that each new urban activity we introduce
will have a different appropriate size of market area and spacing of supply
centers. The appropriate area will be small, and the centers closely spaced,
for products for which there is little economy in agglomeration or for which
the density of market demand is high. Where the contrary conditions hold
(important agglomeration economies or sparse demand), we should expect
production to be concentrated in a few widely spaced centers each serving a
large area.9
But should
we really expect to find as many different and independent systems of market
areas and production centers as there are different productsan almost
infinite variety? We might expect this were it not for the economic advantages
of channelizing transfer along a limited number of efficient routes, and the
advantages of clustering different activities in the same place so as to get
the external economies of agglomeration discussed in Chapter 5. Recalling those considerations, we can
see why two or more activities for which the "ideal" pattern of centers may be
only slightly different are, in fact, likely to settle for a common
"compromise" set of production locations. And if two activities do have very
different ideal sizes of areas, the tendency is for the activity with the
larger-sized areas to locate at some of the centers of the other
activitysay every other one, or every third, fourth, or tenth one. In
this way, each activity can have a pattern of centers more or less
appropriately spaced to fit its conditions, while at the same time the total
number of centers is kept down. This is an advantage because bigger centers
provide more economies of agglomeration and because more of the total flow of
goods and services can travel on efficient high-volume transfer
routes.
The
pressure for reduction of the number of size classes of areas is so basic that
we might even embellish the vocabulary of regional economics by referring here
to a Procrustean Law of market areas. Procrustes was a mythical
innkeeper who provided only one bed for all his guests and achieved a perfect
fit by stretching or cropping each guest as required.
What all
this implies is a hierarchy of central places. As this sorting takes
place and activities with larger-sized ideal areas locate at some of the
centers of other activities, this results in some central places having a
greater variety of goods. As the number of activities becomes large, we can
envision some centers with a much more complete set of activities than other
centers. A stylized example of such a system is shown in Figure 8-3. In this particular hierarchical pattern, it
is assumed that the areas are square. Four "orders" or size classes of centers
are represented by different sizes of dots, and their respective areas are
bounded by black and gray lines (shown at the right of the figure).
There are
many possible variations on this scheme; they have been analyzed in detail for
both the square and the hexagonal systems and need not detain us here. However,
one particular feature is important for an understanding of urban and regional
structure. In the system of cities shown in Figure
8-3, each city of any but the smallest size class serves as the center not
only for its area but also for an area of each of the smaller sizes. The
implication is, in fact, that each order of centers carries on the
activities of all lower orders of centers plus some further activities not
found in such places. Thus even in the largest city, retail customers have
the opportunity to buy goods and services found also in the smallest hamlet,
but retail customers in smaller places inevitably must look to larger towns for
some of their shopping needs.
As we shall
see from some empirical evidence to be introduced later, the mix of activities
in urban places of various sizes does in fact conform rather closely to what we
should expect under a fully hierarchical organization of this sort. Larger
centers do have most if not all of the kinds of urban activities found in
smaller centers.
Another
feature of the central-place hierarchy characterized in Figure 8-3 is that it exhibits a constant nesting
factor (in this case, 2). That is, market-area size (i.e., the physical
extent of the market) increases from one level of the hierarchy to the next by
a constant factor, so that the number of market areas of one size class that
nest into the next largest size class does not vary as one proceeds through the
hierarchy. Central-place models need not have this attribute, although the
hierarchy developed by Christaller did. John B. Parr has developed a more
general system that allows for variability in the nesting factor.10 As a result, the ratio at which market-area size
increases from one level of the hierarchy to the next may differ at each step
up the ladder. This flexibility has the potential of contributing significantly
to the descriptive power of central-place models.
The basic
concept of a central-place hierarchy contributes importantly to our
understanding of intraurban location patterns. In the preceding chapter,
we identified the phenomenon of subcenters as an elementary characteristic of
urban spatial structure. Having recognized the interurban hierarchy of central
places, it is but a small extension to view the subcenters found within
metropolitan areas as central places on a more micro level.11 Corresponding to the central-place hierarchy of
hamlet, convenience center, shopping center, and wholesale-retail center in
terms of urban places, we have an intraurban subcenter hierarchy of
streetcorner, neighborhood, and community center with progressively greater
size, variety, and market area.
8.2.4
Some Practical limitations
The highly
simplified central-place model presented so far provides a rationale for
patterns of cities such as the one shown in Figure
8-3. There are many size classes of cities; each larger class has a more
comprehensive array of urban activities and comprises a smaller number of
cities spaced farther apart. We should expect the various extensive rural
activities (for example, distinctive types of agriculture) to be arranged in
concentric zones around the centers, in the manner shown in Figure 6-4. Any given city above the lowest order will
have more than one rural market area (for its various outputs) and more than
one rural supply area (for its various rurally produced inputs); there is no
reason to expect any of its market areas to coincide with any of its supply
areas. In addition, all cities except those in the largest class may be getting
urban products from cities of larger size.
This is
obviously not an adequate picture of cities, areas, and trade flows in the real
world. We begin now to consider some of the additional factors
involved.
First, the
simple model assumed a uniform transfer cost per mile on a fine and regular
grid of routes, and also assumed that the rural market was distributed with
uniform density. Recognition of a less regular transfer network, with some
routes cheaper or better than others, and recognition of variations in the
density of demand, would lead us to expect substantial deformation of the areas
and city patterns. Still further deformation arises because the costs of inputs
and the resulting costs of production are not really the same in different
cities, even among those of the same size class. The many activities that are
sensitive to location factors other than agglomeration economies and access to
markets were ignored in the simple model; superimposing their locations on the
basic central-place scheme further complicates the pattern, creating additional
cities (and! or larger cities) by adding both more urban activity and more
demand. Finally, the whole pattern of locations is constantly shifting in
delayed response to changes in such conditions as population, regional income
levels, transfer costs, and technology, so that no picture of an equilibrium
situation can be realistic.
These
practical considerations are ample to explain why the distribution of cities by
size is not stepwise by discrete hierarchical classes but continuous;12 and also why there are only loose relations
between the population of a city and the size of its trading area, and between
city size and the range of activities represented in a city.
8.2.5
Generalized Areas of Urban Influence
Although
the central-place model described implies that any city above the smallest
class has a variety of different-sized market and supply areas, people
frequently refer to "the" trading area (or tributary area, or area of
dominance) of a city, as if there were only one. The identification of
appropriate and useful nodal regions, which will be taken up later, relies
heavily on the notion that for a considerable range of purposes (though
perhaps not for all purposes) we can mark out some single area as particularly
related to a given center.
For
example, in one of the early studies of spatial trading patterns by marketing
specialist William J. Reilly, an attempt was made to induce an empirical
formula to explain retail trading areas of cities in terms of their
size.13 Reilly's
Law of Retail Gravitation says that "two cities attract retail trade from
any intermediate city or town in the vicinity of the breaking point [the
boundary between their spheres of dominance], approximately in direct
proportion to the populations of the two cities and in inverse proportion to
the squares of the distance from these two cities to the intermediate
town."14
Some
overlap of market areas is recognized, but according to this law, the
market-area boundary in the sense of the "breaking point" (where trade is
equally distributed between the two supplying cities) runs through points
where
if PAand PB are the respective
populations of the two cities A and B, and DA and DB are their respective distances from the
boundary. This means that if A and B are of equal size, the
market-area boundary is a straight line midway between them; but if, for
example, A is twice as large as B, each point on the market-area
boundary is times as far
from A as from B. Figure 8-4 shows a hypothetical set of four
centers and their areas.15 Reillys Law
worked reasonably well when tested against actual situations (which might be
expected since it was derived empirically rather than theoretically) and has
proved more durable than many other "laws." Let us see how it might be
rationalized in terms of the simple central-place model by making the situation
a little more realistic.
Consider a
rural family living midway between a small town and a somewhat larger town. If
they want to buy gasoline or a loaf of bread, there will be no particular
reason to prefer one town to the other, and shopping trips wholly devoted to
such "convenience purchases" would tend to be about equally divided. If the
trip is to include going to a movie or buying a suit of clothes, however, the
preference would be for the larger town, since its clothing stores have a wider
selection and it may have two movie theaters compared to one in the smaller
town. Trips of this sort, then, will be directed predominantly to the larger
shopping center. Finally, there are some things (perhaps binoculars, or parts
for the washing machine) that cannot be purchased at all in the smaller town
but are available in the larger one. Any shopping trip including such an errand
will have to be directed to the larger town.
The relative populations of
the four towns, A,B,C, and D are as indicated in parentheses.
As trading area includes all territory outside the circles. All
boundaries consist of circular arcs.
For obvious
reasons of economy of time and money, people try to consolidate their errands
and perform multipurpose trips. It is clear, then, that the majority of trips
for this family located at the half-way point will be in the direction of the
larger town because of the greater range of its activities. To find a family
that splits its trips evenly between the two towns (that is, to locate the
trading-area boundary) we would have to go some distance down the road toward
the smaller town.
8.3 TRADE CENTERS IN AN AMERICAN REGION-THE UPPER MIDWEST
STUDY
The
applicability and relevance of the central-place approach is brought out in a
study made in the mid-1960s of urban places in the Upper Midwest, a large area
defined for purposes of the study as coterminous with the Ninth Federal Reserve
District. This study was part of a much larger project analyzing economic
activity and trends in the area.16
The purpose
of this investigation was to provide some guidance to planning and development
activities involving cities and towns in the Upper Midwest region. No attempt
was made to predict growth or recommend development policies for any specific
urban place. But as a basis for any subsequent efforts with such local
application, the study developed some interesting and useful findings regarding
the characteristics and growth trends of categories of places,
corresponding conceptually to the "orders" of the theoretical central-place
hierarchy.
The first
step was a listing of retail and wholesale activities, arranged according to
the smallest size of community in which they are consistently represented. Figure 8-5 shows this grouping and the way in which it
was applied in classifying the individual trade centers. Thus in order to rank
as a "minimum convenience" center, a place had to have all of the last six
activities shown, and at least two of the preceding four (garage, auto,
implement dealer; variety store; meat, fish, fruit; general merchandise). To
qualify for the highest rank,17 a trade
center had to have every one of the activities listed. The category of "hamlet"
was added as the lowest order of trading center. In general, hamlets contained
a gasoline station and an eating place but no consistent set of further trade
activities.
In all,
more than 2200 centers were thus classified (see maps, Figure 8-6eand Figure 8-6w). Table 8-1 shows the numbers and sizes by hierarchy
level. It will be observed that the higher orders of centers are progressively
fewer and larger; but there is much overlapping of size ranges, reflecting the
fact that a centers trading activity is not the sole determinant of its
employment or population.
The study
explicitly recognized that each type of center higher than a hamlet has more
than one size of trade area.18 The
method used to determine the trade areas of the highest orders of centers
(primary and secondary wholesale-retail) was based on relative frequency of
telephone calls. From shopping and convenience centers within its area, a
"wholesale-retail center" received more calls than any other center at its own
level, and at least half as many calls as any "metropolitan center."19
Trade areas
at the "complete shopping" level were "defined by lines drawn at highway
half-distances between complete shopping centers, then adjusted for barriers,
such as mountain ranges, and differences in sizes of competing centers."20 It is interesting to note in Figure 8-6eand Figure
8-6w that these areas are larger (that is, the complete shopping centers
are spaced farther apart) in the western and extreme northeastern parts of the
Upper Midwest, where the density of population and income per square mile is
less. This is in accord with the theoretical expectation indicated earlier:
Trade-area size is inversely related to market density.
Figure 8-7 shows the much larger trade areas at the
"secondary wholesale-retail" level. Here again, the areas are more extensive
where population is sparser, and there is an observable tendency for the areas
to be asymmetrical, extending farther in the direction away from metropolitan
centers. This same asymmetry was noted as a theoretical expectation in Figure 8-4, but there is an additional reason for it.
A large part of the goods distributed from the wholesaling centers are bought
from manufacturers or large distributors in the metropolitan centers and other
places outside the region, and transfer costs make their prices higher as we go
farther from those sources. Consequently, a trade center in the Upper Midwest
can compete more effectively with other centers of its own rank located farther
from the sources of the goods than it can with competing centers located closer
to the sources.
Trade and
service areas of metropolitan centers serving the Upper Midwest are shown in Figure 8-8. This demarcation of areas was based on
relative frequencies of telephone calls received from wholesale-retail centers,
and the progression of frequencies is mapped for Minneapolis, St. Paul. It will
be observed that the number of calls (per 100 inhabitants at the
wholesale-retail centers where the calls originate) first falls off very
rapidly and then more and more gradually with increasing distance from the
metropolitan center.
8.4 ACTIVITIES EXTRANEOUS TO THE CENTRALPLACE
HIERARCHY
Let us now
consider more explicitly some of the limitations of the simple central-place
model. So far in this chapter, our assumption has been that both markets and
sources of transferable inputs for urban activities are uniformly distributed
in space. The resultant theoretical patterns of market areas and central places
simply reflected the locational effects of the economies of agglomeration
available to various kinds of urban activities. We have as yet no rationale for
any flows of goods or services (other than primary rural products) either "up"
the steps of the urban hierarchy or "horizontally" among cities of equal
status. Yet in reality, enormous flows of these types occur. Clevelanders buy
cigarettes from Durham, North Carolina, automobile tires from Akron, frozen
orange juice made in small towns in Florida, and government services from
Washington, D.C., and Columbus, Ohio. How does all this relate, if at all, to
the hierarchical scheme of urban places, activities, and market areas?
The clue is
that neither markets nor transferable inputs are uniformly distributed.
Although for most kinds of consumer goods and services there is a market
wherever people live, there are some consumer goods and services that are used
mainly or exclusively by people in certain regions, by people in larger cities,
or by rural and small-town people. For inputs, the lack of ubiquity is even
more pervasive. Labor supply, of a sort, exists wherever people live; but other
inputssuch as specific crops, minerals, manufactured goods, or
servicesare found only in certain places, and with wide variation in both
cost and quality.
Let us
consider the locational implications. We can usefully distinguish three classes
of activities according to whether their locations are (1) predominantly in
larger cities, (2) predominantly in small cities or towns, or (3) not
associated with any particular size of city. (Certain manufacturing industries
are cited as examples in Appendix 8-2.)
Those
activities dependent on the external economies of urban concentration are predominantly located in large cities. This class of activities has
already been discussed in Chapter 5. Their outputs are disposed of in the
cities where produced, in other cities of all sizes, and in rural areas as
well. In other words, the flow is mainly downward in the hierarchy, but it is
also horizontal at the highest levels. Activities of this type fit reasonably
well into the hierarchical central-place scheme.
There are
several reasons why an activity might be found mainly in small centers. First, this is the normal location pattern for processing operations
strongly oriented to rural inputs or to other inputs derived from extensive
land uses; these uses tend to be crowded out from highly urbanized regions by
more intensive claimants for land. Forestry and grazing are such activities:
Sawmills and meat-packing plants are most often not located in large cities,
because they must be close to types of land use usually associated with sparse
settlement. Meat packing would be even more a small-town industry were it not
for the practice of shipping cattle from range lands to fattening areas prior
to slaughter.21 The processing of perishable
crops is so strongly input-oriented that individual plants have quite small
supply areas; and simply on a probability basis, very few of those areas will
contain a large city.22
Small-town
locations are characteristic for activities associated with extensive outdoor
recreation. These activities need plenty of space, and in some cases (such as
ski resorts) topographical or climatic conditions not typical of large
cities.
Finally,
small cities and towns usually provide lower living costs and wage levels. Thus
activities strongly oriented to cheap labor as such, and footloose with regard
to other locational considerations, are likely to prefer the smallest size
place that will provide enough workers for a plant of efficient scale. Most
American textile mills, and a wide variety of industries making fairly
standardized apparel items (such as shoes), are now found in rather small
cities and towns, the principal explanation being labor-cost economies (Chapter
10 gives further attention to the origins and effects of labor-cost
differentials).
There are
even some basically clerical activities for which a small-town location is
appropriate for serving a nationwide market, since labor and space are cheap,
and the inputs and outputs move by mail. For example, the U.S. Bureau of the
Census maintains its central office for the searching of Census files to
establish birth records for individuals at Pittsburg, Kansas. One of the larger
life insurance companies maintains its central office at the very small city of
Montpelier, Vermont. Most other firms in this field, however, are in larger
cities. For activities located in small cities, the flow of outputs is mainly up the urban hierarchy to markets in larger cities; but it is also
partly horizontal, since only some but not all small places have the activity
in question.
There are a
large variety of activities for which size of city seems essentially
irrelevant. They occur indiscriminately in small, middle-sized, and large
cities. Some of these are primarily oriented to a localized natural advantage
such as water (for processing or for transport) or a mineral resource, and
their agglomeration economies are internal, involving merely the scale of the
individual unit. Thus salt mining and processing works are found both in
isolated locations and within the city of Detroit; steelworks are found both in
large cities such as Chicago and in quite small cities such as Butler,
Pennsylvania, or Provo, Utah; and automobile parts, electrical equipment,
furniture, whiskey, candy, and many other manufactured goods are made in
locations seemingly selected without any systematic concern for city size.
There is no discernible relationship here to the hierarchical scheme of central
places in terms of market areas, industry distribution patterns, or the flow of
inputs or outputs.
In view of
such kinds of activity that do not seem to fit the hierarchical central-place
scheme at all, we can readily understand why the relation of range of
commercial functions to size of trade area and to city size is less than exact.
In fact, it may be surprising that there is as much evidence of hierarchical
regularity as does appear. Let us take another look at the principles
involved.
The
relationship between trade-area size (that is, spacing of cities) and urban
functions principally involves retail and wholesale trade, which were in
fact the basis of the hierarchical ranking in the Upper Midwest investigation.
Some kinds of manufacturing also play a similar role. Bakeries, soft
drink bottling plants, sheet metal shops, ice cream plants, job printing and
newspaper plants, and many other industries can be arranged in a reasonable
sequence according to the minimum size of market required, in the same way that
different lines of trade or services are, and it is possible to identify
roughly the threshold size of place above which each is likely to be
found. Many kinds of services (shoe repairing, movies, bowling alleys,
doctors, lawyers, hospitals, realtors, morticians, broadcasting stations, and
so on) can likewise be more or less appropriately fitted into the central-place
order. Moreover, something very like the trade center hierarchy appears in the public services provided in the hierarchy of unincorporated settlements,
villages, towns, county seats, and state capitals.
But many
urban places, at all size levels, also contain what we can call noncentral-place activities. Consider, for example, a small town whose
retail trading area extends only a dozen miles, but which now acquires a shoe
factory serving a wide regional or even a national market. That town now has a
large employment and population compared to either the size or the population
of its rural trading area. In this respect, it has been put out of line with
the hierarchical scheme. But we must recognize that its trading area includes
itself. The town needs grocery stores, drug stores, and the like to serve the
shoe factory employees as well as the rural customers and the people employed
in central-place activities. Both the amount and the variety of its
central-place business will become greater than they were before the shoe
factory came. Thus the town will occupy a higher rank in the hierarchy. Finally, by virtue of the wider range of available goods, we can expect the
town to draw rural customers from a larger area than before, at the
expense of rival towns not blessed by new factories. (Some of those towns may
as a result lose previous retail functions and sink in the hierarchy.) The
ultimate equilibrium situation may turn out to be reasonably close, after all,
to what the central-place formulas would suggest in terms of the relation
between town size, range of central-place activities, and size of trade
area.
This
example shows that there may be a good deal more relevance in the theoretical
central-place relationships than one might infer, in view of the fact that so
many activities (like the shoe factory in this example) are located
extraneously. It is no longer quite so surprising that we find the degree of
hierarchical regularity that does appear in the real world. We can see also how
individual towns and cities can break out of their positions in the hierarchy
and either rise or fall. The system, even in theory, has internal
mobility.
8.5 TRENDS IN URBAN
PATTERNS
In later
chapters we shall be considering some of the reasons why certain cities and
regions grow faster than others and what some of the major observable trends of
change are. We now consider briefly how the central-place model can throw some
light on changes in the relative importance of cities of different orders of
size.
The Upper
Midwest study and other studies brought to light a tendency for the smaller
trade centers to grow more slowly than the middle-sized and large ones, and it
is clear that a great many hamlets and villages have actually disappeared. Table 8-2 provides some evidence of this
trend.
There is some
tendency for population growth of a place to be directly related to its size,
and hence to its previous growth. This is to be expected throughout the main
agricultural regions of the Upper Midwest since the chief functions of most
communities are trade, service, and agricultural processing. The past thirty
years change in these areas has been characterized by adjustment to
modern transport and modern agricultural methods. Although farm population in
the trade areas of these cities has declined, the value of agricultural
production has been sustained or increased. The changes that have taken place
have involved mainly consolidation and centralization of many business
functions and, hence, employment opportunities. In general, the larger a place
was at the beginning of the automotive era, the better have been its chances to
retain old functions and acquire new ones.23
In this
respect, the experience of the Upper Midwest region is representative of that
of the United States as a whole. Throughout much of this century, population
growth in metropolitan areas exceeded that of nonmetropolitan areas. During the
1970s, however, there was a reversal of this growth pattern.
Table 8-3 shows this turnaround. During the 1960s, the
population in metropolitan areas increased by 17 percent, while the increase in
nonmetropolitan areas was only 4 percent. Since 1970, metropolitan area growth
has been only 9.5 percent, compared with nonmetropolitan growth of 15 percent
and national population growth of approximately 11 percent.
The United
States remains a largely metropolitan nation, with 1980 population figures
indicating that 73 percent of the total population is metropolitan (165.2
million in a total population of 225.5 million). However, the contribution of
metropolitan areas to the national population increase has changed
substantially. During the 1970s, the nations population increased by 22.2
million. Of this increase, only 14.3 million, or roughly two-thirds, occurred
in metropolitan areas. By comparison, 92 percent of the nations growth
was accounted for by the same metropolitan areas during the 1960s.
We observe
also in Table 8-3 that the percentage increase in population growth for the
largest metropolitan areas is substantially less than that for other
metropolitan areas during the 1970s. Again, this reverses a pattern that had
prevailed through the 1960s. Several of the nations largest metropolitan
areasincluding New York, Boston, Philadelphia, Buffalo, Pittsburgh,
Cleveland, Detroit, Milwaukee, and St. Louishad declining population
during the 1970s. Of these, only Pittsburgh had lost population during the
1960s.24
The
abruptness of the turnaround as reflected in these figures is to some extent
deceptive. William Alonso has observed that the demographic forces affecting
population changes in metropolitan areas began to take shape well before
1970.
By the
1960s ... the migration rate into metropolitan areas was small, and
three-fourths of metropolitan population growth was based on natural increase,
and only one-ninth on migration from nonmetropolitan areas, the balance
resulting from immigration from abroad. Now the decline in the rate of natural
increase has cut the growth rate sharply, and this has been accented by the
reversal of net migration into nonmetropolitan areas. 25
Thus it
seems that the decline in the populations natural rate of increase
(defined as the birth rate minus the death rate) has merely exposed some
long-standing economic forces governing migration patterns.26
Table 8-4 offers additional insight on the character of
nonmetropolitan growth. Here the nonmetropolitan population is classified as
residing in incorporated places of different size classes and in unincorporated
areas. We find that the inverse relationship between the size of the population
in a place and its growth, so characteristic of metropolitan areas in the
1970s, extends to very small incorporated areas. However, the percentage
increase in population of these places is modest when compared to the
percentage increase in population for the nation as a whole over this period,
which was approximately 11 percent (as shown in Table
8-3). Table 8-4 shows that only settlements with
1980 populations below 2500 grew faster than the national average. In contrast,
the population growth outside of incorporated cities, towns, and villages has
been substantial. Thus nonmetropolitan growth in recent years is not simply
urban growth on a small scale.
In some
instances, the population trends described above reflect changes that have
occurred within the central-place hierarchy. In others, changes that are
largely extraneous to that hierarchy have been most important. In either case,
however, the effects of these changes are transmitted throughout the
central-place system. We therefore turn to this model for some perspective on
these developments.
Trends of
the sort documented above may result from a tendency for many specific
central-place activities to assume a more concentrated or a more dispersed
pattern (i.e., abandoning smaller places in favor of larger ones or the
reverse) because of changes in the basic conditions determining their efficient
scale and degree of dispersion. These conditions we have identified as (1) the
density of demand for their outputs, (2) the degree to which they are subject
to scale or other agglomeration economies, and (3) the level of transfer costs
on their outputs.27
Increased
density of demand makes it possible for the activity to sustain itself with
smaller trade areas; by the same token, when demand density declines, fewer
centers and areas can survive. In many agricultural sections of the Upper
Midwest and elsewhere, the farm population has been thinning out for several
decades because of the trend toward larger and more mechanized farms employing
fewer people on any given area. The American farm population has been shrinking
rather steadily for nearly half a century. While the rate of decline slowed
somewhat during the 1970s, the long-term downward trend has persisted,28 and the increases in nonmetropolitan population
that took place during the 1970s were almost entirely in nonfarm areas.29 In many areas, of course, per capita farm income
rose more than enough to compensate; but it is reasonable to surmise that a
smaller number of farmers, even without a drop in their aggregate real income,
represents a reduced demand for the kinds of goods and services available in
the smallest settlements. At the same time, there has been a tendency for more
farmers to live in town and commute to their farms, or to move to town in the
winter. Consequently, farm population trends appear to provide some of the
explanation for the slow growth or decline of the smallest trade centers prior
to 1970.
The recent
growth in nonmetropolitan populations also has implied shifts in the density of
demand. Table 8-3 indicates that suburban development beyond officially
recognized metropolitan-area boundaries accounts for some nonmetropolitan
growth, both in the 1960s and in the 1970s. In each decade, nonmetropolitan
counties closest to urban centers (those with 30 percent or more commuting) had
large percentage changes in population. Estimates by the Bureau of the Census
suggest that one-fourth to one-third of nonmetropolitan growth can be
attributed to this outer suburban or "exurban" development.30
This is not
the only source of increased density of demand in smaller central places,
however. Counties that had high concentrations of retirees in 1970 also had
substantial population growth in the decade to follow.31 The importance of this phenomenon for some
nonmetropolitan areas is obvious (as in many parts of Florida and Arizona, for
example), but its significance is much more general. An extensive analysis by
Kevin F. McCarthy and Peter A. Morrison of population growth rates by counties
in 26 states during the first half of the 1970s shows sharp gains in growth
rates for areas that they classify as specializing in retirement, particularly
in rural and less urban areas.32 They also
find that nonmetropolitan counties specializing in recreation posted similarly
impressive gains. It appears that these amenity-rich areas may be a major
beneficiary of higher levels of national income and increases in leisure
time.
Increased
economies of scale for an activity have the effect of enlarging trade areas and
concentrating the activity in fewer and larger urban centers. Scale economies
have not been as conspicuously enhanced in trade activities as in industrial
activities; but the modern supermarket and shopping center have developed
mainly within the past generation and constitute a major change. We must also
reckon with the fact that higher living standards make consumers more sensitive
to the appeals of variety in shopping goods and hence add to the competitive
advantages of larger trading centers that can provide such a variety.
Recognition of scale economies has been evidenced also in the trend toward
consolidation and concentration of many public activities, such as schools and
health services. Thus on the whole, this factor has probably contributed to
faster growth of middle-sized and larger trade centers at the expense of
smaller ones.
The spread of good roads
and automobile ownership has, of course, enabled rural and small-town people to
make longer shopping, crop-delivery, and other trips, and this factor also
should be recognized as part of the explanation for the observed trends of
urban growth. But the effect of changes in the level of transfer costs on
trade-area size and on the spacing of trading centers is less straightforward
than it might appear.
If transfer
were assumed to be altogether costless, urban activities could be concentrated
at the points of lowest operating cost, and economies of agglomeration would
tend to concentrate all of an activity in one place. At the other extreme, if
transfer were infinitely costly (that is, impossible), each location would have
to be self-sufficient. From this contrast of extremes, we might infer that
cheaper transfer always enlarges trade areas and leads to fewer, larger, and
more widely spaced central places. A similar inference could be drawn by
regarding transfer services and the services of factors of production as
complementary inputs, with possibilities of substituting a cheaper input for a
more expensive one. Then if transfer services became cheaper, we should expect
that more transfer would be used in relation to output: that is, distances
between seller and buyer would increase and trading areas would be larger. This
is what we may call the substitution effect of a change in transfer
cost.
This simple
formulation, however, overlooks some side effects of changes in the level of
transfer cost. First, there is what might be called the income effect of
such changes. If transfer becomes cheaper, buyers at any distance from the
trade center will get the goods cheaper and will normally buy more. With
greater sales per buyer, a smaller trade area will suffice to provide the scale
economies needed to sustain a center. More centers will be able to survive. The
income effect of a reduction in transfer costs, then, is a reduction in
trade-area size, and it is similar to the effect of an increase in demand
density (that is, population density, per capita income, or both).33
There is
another way, too, in which cheaper transport may tend to reduce the size of
trading areas and lead to a more dispersed pattern of centers. The degree to
which activity is concentrated in locations of low operating cost depends on
(1) transfer costs and (2) the magnitude of the differentials in operating
cost. If transfer becomes cheaper while the operating cost differentials remain
the same, urban activity will become less transfer-oriented and will tend to
cluster more in efficient operating locations. But in fact, reduced transfer
costs are likely to narrow the operating cost differentials, insofar as they
enhance the mobility of labor and other production factor inputs. Here again, a
change in the level of transfer cost cuts both ways in regard to agglomeration
versus dispersion, and the net effect could be in either direction.34
Changes in
the basic conditions determining the efficient scale and dispersion of
activitiessuch as those conditions discussed aboveare not the only
reason for the changes we observe in the urban place pattern. The structure of
the hierarchy is affected also by changes in the mix of activities. It has been
mentioned already that, as a result of higher levels of income and leisure,
consumer demand tends to shift from staple necessities to a wider range of
shopping goods and luxuries, with variety becoming a more important dimension
of competitive advantage for producers. While this clearly favors the large
trade center, we must also recognize that the national economy is becoming much
more dependent on service activities and much less dependent on manufacturing
per Se. As population in nonmetropolitan areas increases, the growth of
services will follow, since services are highly oriented toward their
respective markets. This fact is surely reflected in the population growth
associated with nonmetropolitan areas having high concentrations of retirees or
specializing in recreation that were noted above.
The
framework of the central-place model is relevant in assessing some of the
factors governing trends in urban patterns. However, a number of trends in
noncentral-place activities must also be considered. Generally, as the economy
develops, a greater proportion of productive activities involves later stages
of processing and handling, and a smaller proportion uses rural products
directly as inputs. Fewer and fewer activities need to be oriented closely to
inputs from rural extractive activity (as do canneries or sawmills); in
contrast, there is the widening range of activities (such as the production of
electrical equipment, pharmaceuticals, or books) that are technologically
remote from any extractive process. Accordingly, there is less and less reason
for many activities to be located in small settlements for the sake of easy
access to agricultural, forest, or mineral products. Finally, the increasing
variety and complexity of goods, services, and productive operations in general
calls for more close inter-firm and interactivity contact, and tends to
increase the locational importance of urban external economies of
agglomeration.
Until very
recently, each of these factors contributed to the advantages held by larger
metropolitan areas for manufacturing activity. However, technological advances
in production have begun to alter this pattern. Considerable simplification has
occurred in some production processes that had involved the acquisition of
mechanical components in order to assemble machines or other goods.
Developments in electronics have contributed to this trend and have changed
interindustry relations significantly. Now, one printed circuit or microchip
may substitute effectively for numerous other parts. As the importance of these
"high-technology" goods has increased, the bond of agglomeration economies that
had so strongly influenced location patterns has loosened; proximity to a wide
array of parts suppliers is no longer essential. These modern components are
easily transported, thus freeing both the producer of high-technology goods and
the industrial user to evaluate a wider range of location alternatives. For
some, this has meant taking advantage of relatively low wages and living costs
in nonmetropolitan areas. As discussed in Chapter
3, improvements in information storage, retrieval, and transmission
facilitate such choices.35
While one
might portray this as a technological change in one activity (electronics) that
has affected other activities in an exogenous way, some researchers see it as
part of a larger endogenous process in the life cycle of many different
manufactured goods. They argue that over time, the standardization of
production processes takes place. Once this occurs, decentralization of
activities can be expected, since they are no longer tied by agglomeration
economies to large urban complexes. In this analysis, the diffusion of
technology to more peripheral areas also enhances the potential for innovation
in these regions at the expense of innovation potential in older industrial
centers, thus promoting further decentralization.36
8.6 SUMMARY
Central-place theory attempts to explain the spatial patterns of
trade and service centers. According to this line of analysis, centers for the
distribution of some single good or service to users scattered uniformly over
an area would develop at equidistant sites. Their market areas would all be of
a uniform size determined by transfer costs on the output, density of demand
per unit area, and scale economies in the production and/or marketing of the
output.
These
market-area determinants would ideally call for a different uniform size of
trading areas, and a finer or coarser scatter of distribution centers or
central places, for each kind of output. But because of external economies of
agglomeration and the economies of channeling transfer along high-volume
routes, many different kinds of trade are conducted in a single central place;
and instead of a separate set of centers to handle each product, there is
evolved a rough hierarchy of central places. Central places range from very
small and simple ones carrying on only one or two lines of highly local trade,
through higher classes of central places progressively larger, more widely
separated, and having more different lines of trade and sizes of trading areas.
In the hierarchy, each size class of places carries on all the trading
activities practiced in all lower size classes, plus some further types of
activity not found in any smaller centers.
The
spatial, functional, and size distributions of trading centers in the real
world, as identified in such empirical investigations as the Upper Midwest
Economic Study, conform only roughly to the simplified ideal central-place
model, because many additional location factors affect the growth of specific
activities in specific centers, and neither transfer costs nor demand densities
are actually uniform. Such studies are, however, useful in assessing the
changing roles of urban centers of various size classes and trading functions
in a regional economy when population, income, and transfer and other
technologies change. In the United States, trends toward concentration of more
trading activities in larger centers, lengthening of the retail buyers
journey, and relative decay of many of the smallest settlements can be
logically explained in terms of a central-place model.
The trading
areas of larger centers are enlarged by the attraction that variety holds for
shoppers and the fact that people often combine purchases of different types on
a single trip. A larger center has also some lines of trade in which
trading-area radii are characteristically larger than those of the businesses
found in smaller places. An empirical measurement of this size relation was
stated in Reillys Law, a gravity formulation that makes a centers
trading-area radius proportional to the square root of its
population.
The
assumptions of central-place theory are clearly inapplicable to many urban
activities (including most kinds of manufacturing). Some of those activities
appear to locate without regard to city size. It is possible, however, to
identify empirically certain groups of activities that are relatively
concentrated in specific size classes of cities and to explain such
concentration patterns in terms of considerations complementary to the
central-place model.
The United
States has experienced major changes in the relative importance of cities of
different orders of size. With the 1970s came the reversal of a long-standing
trend toward greater growth rates in larger metropolitan areas. Explanations of
these developments lie within the central-place framework as well as beyond it.
Regardless of the source of these changes, however, the effects are distributed
throughout the urban hierarchy.
TECHNICAL TERMS INTRODUCED IN THIS CHAPTER |
Central
place |
Rank-Size
Rule |
Hierarchy of central
places |
Threshold size of
place |
Market
density |
Location quotient (p.
237) |
Nesting
factor |
|
SELECTED READINGS
Martin Beckmann, Location Theory (New York: Random House, 1968), Chapter 5.
Dennis R. Capozza and Kazem
Attaran, "Pricing in Urban Areas Under Free Entry," Journal of Regional
Science, 16, 2 (August 1976), 167-182.
M. L. Greenhut and H. Ohta, Theory of Spatial Pricing and Market Areas (Durham, N.C.: Duke
University Press, 1975).
Edgar M. Hoover, "Transport
Costs and the Spacing of Central Places,"Papers of the Regional Science
Association, 25 (1970), 255-274.
Charles L. Leven (ed.), The Mature Metropolis (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, D. C. Heath,
1978), pp. 23-41.
August Lösch, Die
räumliche Ordnung der Wirtschaft (Jena: Gustav Fischer, 1940; 2nd ed.,
1944); W. H. Woglom (tr.), The Economics of Location (New Haven, Conn.:
Yale University Press, 1954).
Hugh 0. Nourse, Regional
Economics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1968), Chapter 3.
John B. Parr, "Models of
the Central Place System: A More General Approach," Urban. Studies, 15,
1 (February 1978), 35-49.
Harry W. Richardson, Regional Economics (New York: Praeger, 1969), Chapter 7.
APPENDIX 8-1
Trading-Area Boundaries
Under Reillys Law see link
Assume two centers A and B located w miles apart, with center A having m times the population of center B. According to Reillys Law,
the square of the distance from A to any point on the trading-area
boundary will be m times the square of the distance from B to
that point.
In
this diagram, the locations are plotted with A at the origin and B on the horizontal axis at a distance w. A point X on the
boundary is shown with coordinates x and y.
Reillys Law may now
be stated as
y2 + x2=m(y2 + x2 2xw + w2)
(1)
y2(l m) =x2(1 rn) 2xmw + w2m (2)
y2 =w2m/(1 m) 2xmw/(1 rn) x2 (3)
Let
z =x + mw/(1 m)
(4)
Then
z2=x2 + 2xmw/(1 rn) + [mw/(1 m)]2 (5)
-x2=-z2 + 2xmw/(1 m) + [mw/(1
m)]2 ( 6)
Substituting in
(3),
y2=rnw2/(1 m) 2xmw/(1
m) z2 (7)
+2xmw/(1 m) + [mw/(1 rn)]2
y2=[(mw2 m2w2 + m2w2)/(1 m)2] z2 (8)
y2 ± z2=mw2/(1 m)2 (9)
This is the equation of a
circle with radius
The center of the circle is
at z =0. Substituting in (4),
x=inw/(m1) (10)
The distance of the center
of the circle from A is thus m/(m 1) times the distance w from A to B. If m > 1 (that is, if A has the larger population), the center will then be to the right of B in the diagram, by a distance mw/(m 1) w =w/(m 1).
In the
special case of equal populations (m =1), there is no circle but a
straight-line boundary, the perpendicular bisector of the line AB. Its
equation is x =w/2.
APPENDIX 8-2
Concentration of U.S. Manufacturing Industries by Size Class of
City (see section 8.4)
In section 8.4, a possible locational categorization of
activities was suggested, according to whether the activity tends to locate
predominantly (1) in large cities, (2) in small cities, or (3) without regard
to city size. Some tabulations of Census data by the U.S. Department of
Commerce provide the basis for such a categorization of all manufacturing industries on the rather detailed four-digit level of the Standard
Industrial Classification. The data are from the Census of Manufactures,
1954.
The
relative concentration of specific industries in specific size classes of
cities is measured here by location quotients. A location quotient is a
statistical measure of the degree to which any two quantitative characteristics
are dissimilarly distributed between any two areas. Call the characteristics X
and Y and the areas A and B, and let XA represent
the amount of characteristic X in area A, and so on. Then the location
quotient is (XA/XB) ÷ (YA/YB). An alternative way of expressing the same
quotient is (XA/YA) ÷ (XB/YB). Both formulas give exactly the same
result, since both are equal to (XA YB)/(XBYA). The location quotient will be
used a number of times later in this book.
In the case
in hand, the areas are (A) a given size class of cities and (B) the United States as a whole, and the characteristics are (X) employment in a given manufacturing industry and (Y) employment in all
manufacturing industries combined. Thus the location quotient for any given
industry and size class of city is obtained by dividing the size classs
fraction of U.S. employment in the given industry
(XA/XB)) by its fraction of U.S. employment in all
industries (YA/YB).
The set of
location quotients for any given industry gives a profile of that
industrys location pattern in relation to size class of cityfor
example, if the quotients are higher for the larger size classes, we can say
that the industry in question tends to be more than proportionately represented
in large cities.
Table 8-2-1 presents some illustrative findings. For
each city size, a few industries have been picked out that most clearly show
the specific concentration pattern indicated. It is interesting to note that
all of the first group of industries (concentrated in the largest cities)
appear also in the list of "external-economy industries" highly concentrated in
New York (see Table 5-1). Table 8-2-1 includes
also, at the end, a list of industries that seem to be located without regard
to city size, since their location quotients for the different size classes all
lie within a rather narrow range.
ENDNOTES
1. For convenience we shall often use the term "city" to mean any
urban place, regardless of size.
2. The word "historical" is not meant to imply any lack of relevance
to the future. The characteristic of the approach described here is that it
considers changes (past and prospective) in specific cities. A pioneer
American study along these lines was Adna F. Weber, The Growth of Cities in
the Nineteenth Century, Columbia University Studies in History, Economics,
and Public Law, 11 (New York: Macmillan, 1899; rev. ed., Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell
University Press, 1963). There are also countless histories of the origin and
development of individual cities.
3. The self-reinforcing nature of urban growth, in a particular
historical context, is especially well brought out in Allen R. Pred, The
Spatial Dynamics of US. Urban-Industrial Growth, 1800-1914 (Cambridge,
Mass.: MIT Press, 1966).
4. Wilbur R. Thompson, A Preface to Urban Economics (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1965), p. 24.
5. Walter Christaller, Die zentralen Orte in Süddeutschland (Jena: Gustav Fischer, 1933); C. W. Baskin (tr.), Central Places in
Southern Germany (Englewood Cliffs N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1966). An abstract
of the theoretical parts of Christallers work appears in Brian J. L.
Berry and Allen R. Pred, Central Place Studies: A Bibliography of Theory and
Applications (Philadelphia: Regional Science Research Institute, 1961). See
also August Lösch, Die räumliche Ordnung der Wirtschaft (Jena:
Gustav Fischer, 1940); W. H. Woglom with the assistance of W. F. Stolper
(trs.), The Economics of Location (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University
Press, 1954). Berrys definitive article, "Cities as Systems Within
Systems of Cities" (which deals also with intracity location patterns), first
appeared in Papers of the Regional Science Association. 13 (1964),
147-163.
6. In Lösch, Economics of Location, pp. 105 ff., the two
activities were exemplified as agriculture and commercial brewing respectively.
The brewers need grain and other farm products, and the farmers need
beer.
7. In addition to the material in Section 4.2.2 concerning the market area of
a spatial monopolist, the reader is referred to Appendix 4-1, where the relationship
between pricing policies and conditions determining the existence and size of
market areas is discussed in greater depth.
8. Martin Beckmann, Location Theory (New York: Random House,
1968), pp. 46-47.
Also, it
should be noted that the requirement of "space-filling" shapes is not
particularly descriptive of real-world situations. It implies that no buyer is
excluded from purchasing a good because of transfer costs. In fact, transfer
costs do make the delivered price of some goods prohibitively high in many
locations.
9. It might appear obvious as well that products with lower
transfer costs (per unit quantity and distance) would he produced in fewer
centers, and distributed over larger market areas, than products with higher
transfer costs. For reasons that will be shown later in this chapter, however,
no such simple general statement about the relation of transfer costs to area
size can be made.
10. John B. Parr, "Models of the Central Place System: A
More General Approach," Urban Studies, 15, 1 (February 1978),
35-49.
11. See Brian J. L. Berry, "Research Frontiers in Urban
Geography," in Philip M. Hauser and Leo F. Schnore (eds.), The Study of
Urbanization (New York: Wiley, 1965), pp. 407-408. Berrys article, in
bibliographical notes appended on pp. 424-430, cites literature on both
interurban and intraurban applications of central-place analysis.
12. The size distribution of cities within a large and
relatively self-contained area has been found empirically to resemble a
particular form described by the Rank-Size Rule. In its simplest
formulation, this rule states that the size of a city is inversely proportional
to its rank. Thus the second biggest city would be half the size of the
biggest, the third biggest would he one-third the size of the biggest, the
500th biggest 1/500 the size of the biggest, and so on. This rule, originally
wholly empirical, has been extensively tested, modified, and given some
theoretical rationalization by Berry, Mills, and others. See Edwin S. Mills, Urban Economics (Glenview, Ill.: Scott, Foresman, 1972), Chapter 7; and
Harry W. Richardson, "Theory of the Distribution of City Sizes: Review and
Prospects," Regional Studies, 7,3 (September 1973), 239-251.
13. William J. Reilly, Methods for the Study of
Retail Relationships, University of Texas Bulletin 2944 (Austin: University
of Texas, 1929; reprinted, 1959); and The Law of Retail Gravitation (New
York: Knickerbocker Press, 1931; 2nd ed., Pillsbury Publishers, 1953).
Reillys analysis was mentioned above in introducing the "potential" or
"gravity model" concept.
14. Ibid., p. 9.
15. If
there are two cities w miles apart, one of which has a population m times that of the other, it can be shown that the market-area boundary
according to Reillys Law is a circle of radius (w Ö m)(m 1) with its center w /(m
1) miles from the smaller city, in the direction away from the larger city. The
larger citys market area completely surrounds that of the smaller city.
See Appendix 8-1 for derivation of these formulas, which
were used in constructing Figure 8-4. The centers of the circles are marked by
small crosses in the figure.
16. See James M. Henderson and Anne 0. Krueger, National Growth and Economic Changes in the Upper Midwest (Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press, 1965), for the final general report on
"the economic development phase of the Upper Midwest Economic Study
(UMES) research program" and a listing of earlier reports. The results of the
UMES Urban Research Program were published in a series of eight Urban Reports
by John R. Borchert and others, listed ibid. p. 228. The material quoted in
this chapter is taken from John R. Borchert and Russell B. Adams, Trade
Centers and Trade Areas of the Upper Midwest, Upper Midwest Economics
Study, Urban Report No. 3 (Minneapolis: September 1963).
17. Minneapolis-St. Paul was put in a class by itself in
view of its unique role as the primary center for the entire region.
18. Large centers have multiple trade areas because they
function at more than one level. For example, Fargo-Moorhead has successively
larger trade areas at the complete shopping, secondary, and primary
wholesale-retail levels." Ibid., p. 5.
19. The only metropolitan center within the Upper
Midwest is Minneapolis-St. Paul, but such outside cities as Chicago, Portland,
Seattle, Milwaukee, Des Moines, Omaha, and Denver received substantial
proportions of the calls from nearby parts of the Upper Midwest. (See Figure 8-8.)
20. Ibid, p. 9.
21. The meat-packing industry in the United States is an
interesting example of major locational shift. Initially highly dispersed, in
the days when transport was costly and slow and refrigeration in transit
impracticable, the industry developed massive concentration in the later
nineteenth century at the larger Midwestern citieson the basis of rail
transport of both livestock and meat products and the economical utilization of
by-products. But the ideal weights of transported input and output were never
very different, and in the mid-twentieth century a trend toward
decentralization set in. The giant stockyards and packing plants of Chicago,
Omaha, Kansas City, St. Paul, and other old-time meat-packing centers were much
curtailed during the 1950s and 1960s. Two major factors causing this locational
shift were apparently (1) the shift of consumer markets toward the West Coast
and the Gulf Coast and (2) the greater use of refrigerated transport of meat
products by truck and air freight, without any corresponding improvement in the
transportability of live animals. Facilitating the transfer of output tends, of
course, to move an activity closer to its sources of inputs, and truck shipment
permits more decentralization out of major terminal locations.
22. Flour milling and some other processing activities
involving little if any loss of perishability or bulk and subject to
considerable economies of scale are more often found in middlesized or even
larger cities (such as Buffalo and Minneapolis).
23. John R. Borchert, The Urbanization of the Upper
Midwest: 1930-1960, Upper Midwest Economic Study, Urban Report No. 2
(Minneapolis: February 1963), p. 19
24. U. S. Bureau of the Census, "Standard Metropolitan
Statistical Areas and Consolidated Statistical Areas: 1980," Supplementary
Reports, PC8O-S1-5 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1981), p.
2
25. William Alonso, "The Current Halt in the
Metropolitan Phenomenon," in Charles L. Leven (ed.), The Mature Metropolis (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, D.C. Heath, 1978), p. 28.
26. While Alonsos remarks on this matter concern
only population growth in metropolitan areas, Census data reveal that the relative change in metropolitan versus nonmetropolitan growth has also
been affected by changes in the natural rate of population increase. The rate
of population increase due to the excess of births over deaths has fallen less
in non-metropolitan areas than in metropolitan areas in recent years. Thus some
part of the observed turnaround is due to this factor, though as yet it is not
possible to estimate its importance relative to that of other factors. See
Larry Long and Diana DeAre, "Repopulating the Countryside: A 1980 Census
Trend," Science, 217 (September 1982), p. 1112.
27. For a more advanced treatment of the effect of
changes in such factors on equilibrium market areas, see Dennis R. Capozza and
Kazem Attaran, "Pricing in Urban Areas Under Free Entry," Journal of
Regional Science, 16, 2 (August 1976), 167-182.
28. U. S. Bureau of the Census, jointly with U.S.
Department of Agriculture, Current Population Reports, Series P-27, No. 54, Farm Population of the United States: 1980 (Washington, D.C.: Government
Printing Office, 1981).
29. U. S. Bureau of the Census, Current Population
Reports, Series P-20, No. 363, Population Profile of the United States: 1980 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1981), p. 7.
30. Ibid., p. 7.
31. Larry
H. Long and Diana DeAre, Migration to Nonmetropolitan Areas, Special
Demographic Analysis, CDS 80-2, U.S. Bureau of the Census (Washington, D.C.:
Government Printing Office, 1980), p. 1.
32. The
Changing Demographic and Economic Structure of Nonmetropolitan Areas," International Regional Science Review, 2, 1 (Winter 1977),
123-142.
33. Where travel by retail buyers is involved, the
benefit to the buyers is mainly a saving in time rather than money. To this
extent, the transfer-cost reduction in itself does not increase effective
market density and shrink trade areas as the income effect implies; the
substitution effect dominates, and buyers respond to easier transfer by using
more transfer (that is, traveling greater distances in search of cheaper or
better goods and services).
The reader
with some training in economics will recognize this conflict between
substitution effect and income effect as something that quite generally occurs
whenever an activity calls for two or more complementary inputs that are to
some extent mutually substitutable. For example, if machinery becomes cheaper,
there is an incentive to add machines and reduce employment; but at the
same time, the cheaper machinery leads to a cheaper product and greater sales,
which increases the demand for labor. The net effect on labor
demand depends upon the terms of substitution between the two inputs and upon
the elasticity of demand for the product.
34. For further discussion of transfer cost effects in
the framework of simplified central-place models, see Walter Isard, Location
and Space-Economy (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1956), pp. 86-87; Hugh 0.
Nourse, Regional Economics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1968), pp. 215-216;
Edgar M. Hoover, "Transport Costs and the Spacing of Central Places," Papers
of the Regional Science Association, 25 (1970), 255-274; and Capozza and
Attaran, "Pricing in Urban Areas."
35. For further reading on the causes and consequences
of slow growth and decline in large metropolitan areas, see Charles L. Leven
(ed.), The Mature Metropolis (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, D. C.
Heath, 1978).
36. See R. D. Norton and J. Bees, "The Product Cycle and
the Spatial Decentralization of American Manufacturing," Regional Studies, 13, 2 (August 1979), 141-151.