9.1 THE NATURE OF A REGION
What is a
region? A voluminous and somewhat turgid literature has been devoted to this
question, with a variety of answers. One irreverent suggestion is that a region
means an area which a regional economist gets a grant to study. Be that as it
may, it is clear that the most appropriate and useful definition depends on the
particular purpose to be served.
Common to
all definitions of a region is the idea of a geographical area constituting an
entity, so that significant statements can be made about the area as a whole.
Aggregation into regions is useful in connection with description, because it means that fewer separate numbers or other facts need to be
handled and perceived. Thus for many purposes, totals and averages for a Census
tract or a county are just as informative and much easier to handle and present
than stacks of individual Census returns would be, even if one had access to
them. Similarly, aggregation is obviously economical in connection with analysis of information; and it is particularly important if there is a
good deal of interdependence of units or activities within the area, so that
the whole really is more than merely the sum of its parts. Finally, and for
similar reasons, aggregation is necessary for administration and for the
formulation and implementation of plans and public policies. From this
standpoint at least, the most useful regional groupings are those which follow
the boundaries of administrative jurisdictions.
A normal
attribute of a region is general consciousness of a common regional interest;
this is fortunate because it makes possible some rational collective efforts to
improve regional welfare. The commonality of interests may be reflected in
numerous ways, but basic to this idea is a high degree of correlation of
economic experiences of the regions subareas and interest groups. Since
this correlation can reflect either of two quite distinct features of internal
structure, we distinguish two different types of regions: the homogeneous and
the functional.
A homogeneous region is demarcated on the basis of internal uniformity. The winter wheat belt in the central part of the United States is a
homogeneous agricultural region because all its parts grow the same main crop
in the same way. Some external change, such as a new farm price support or loan
program, a series of drought years, or a change in the world demand for wheat,
will affect all of the region in a similar way; what is true of one part of the
region is true of other parts, and the various parts resemble one another more
than they resemble areas outside the region. The distinctive land-use zones of
the von Thünen model, discussed in Chapter 6,
can be regarded as homogeneous regions. Americas Appalachia and
Italys Mezzogiorno are regions defined on the basis of a common syndrome
of poverty, arrested economic development, and limited human opportunity. On a
microscale, a homogeneous zone or neighborhood within an urban area (such as a
ghetto or other ethnic area, a wholesaling district, or a wealthy suburb) might
for some purposes be regarded as a homogeneous region.
The set of
nonmetropolitan State Economic Areas, established by the U.S. Bureau of the
Census for tabulation of various kinds of data such as migration, presents
still another example. Those State Economic Areas that do not simply coincide
with Metropolitan Statistical Areas are made up by grouping contiguous counties
within a state. The grouping is systematically worked out by computer so that
(with respect to a large number of characteristics such as income level, racial
mix, and principal economic activity) the counties within any one State
Economic Area are highly similar but the different State Economic Areas are
highly dissimilar. The Regional Economics Division of the U.S. Department of
Commerce has similarly developed a breakdown of the whole United States into
eight relatively homogeneous groups of contiguous states (see Figure 9-1).
The
alternative principle of regionalization is based on functional integration rather than homogeneity. Here, the region is composed of areas that exhibit
more interaction with one another than with outside areas: It is the extent of
economic interdependence that serves as a criterion for regional demarcation. Among functional regions one particular type, the nodal region, is of special interest. The structure of a nodal region resembles that of a
living cell or an atom: There is a nucleus and a complementary peripheral area.
The distinction between nodal and non-nodal functional regions has been clearly
described by Lawrence A. Brown and John Holmes:
A nodal region is seen as a special case of a functional region which has a single focal
point and in which the notion of dominance or order is introduced. If a
grouping of locational entities is based on the criterion that within-group
interaction is greater than interaction between groups, without considering the
role of each entity in the interaction pattern, a functional region maintains [sic]. If, on the other hand, grouping is based upon both interactions
between locational entities and the rank or order of one locational entity to
another, and a single locational entity is identified as dominating all others,
a nodal region maintains.1
From
earlier chapters we have gained some understanding of the ways in which
different activities, in the proximity and interdependence associated with
sharing a regional location, affect one anothers development. Thus within
any region, particularly a functional one, there is a vast amount of
transference of goods and services among activities. A furniture factory buys
locally its electricity, labor services, public services, and at least some of
its materials and supplies. A wholesale firm supplies retailers in the region
and gets its labor, public services, and some of its other inputs from inside
the region. Nearly everyone in a region is in fact both a buyer from and a
seller to someone else in the region and thus helps to support the presence of
various other activities.
In addition
to this interdependence through local purchases and sales of goods and
services, regional activities affect one another by competing for space and
other scarce local resources, such as water. Some of these relationships were
explored in Chapter 6.
In Chapter 5 we examined other ways in which
activities in a region affect one another by mutually creating external
economies of agglomeration, and in Chapter 8 we
saw how agglomerative forces give rise to urban concentrations of various sizes
and functional characteristics.
A city and
its surrounding commuting and trading area make a nodal region. The parts with
the main concentration of business and employment are in sharp contrast to the
residential areas, especially to the "bedroom suburbs," but they are tightly
linked to them by flows of commuters, migrants, goods and services, and
payments. Thus the region is usefully considered as a unit in its reaction to
changed conditions affecting economic growth and well-being. Neither core nor
periphery can flourish without the other.
Figure 9-2aand Figure 9-2b shows regions designated as Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas (SMSAs),
which are demarcated on a nodal basis, using such criteria as commuter flows
and circulation areas of metropolitan newspapers. Recently, the term "Standard
Metropolitan Statistical Area" has been shortened to "Metropolitan Statistical
Area." Each designated area must have a nucleus consisting of at least one
"central city," defined to have a population of at least 50,000 or an urbanized
area of at least 50,000 with a total metropolitan population of at least
100,000. Large areas with a population of one million or more, also satisfying
criteria for economic integration, may qualify as Primary Metropolitan
Statistical Areas (PMSAs). Still larger Consolidated Metropolitan Statistical
Areas, comprising two or more PMSAs, are also designated.
At a more
macro level, the concept of functional integration can be used to identify
regions made up of a number of nodal subregions. Again, it is the intensity of
economic interaction that is critical. Movements of goods and services, labor
and money flows, the frequency of telephone calls, or other measures of
transactions among areas, each of which may include one or more cities, can be
used as a basis for recognizing the boundaries of larger spatial
entities.
In the
establishment of planning or administrative "regions," "subregions,"
"districts," or other areas, considerations of homogeneity and functional
integration are both relevant, and so are a variety of special factors in
particular cases. Consider, for example, the cases of river-basin planning,
flood control, defense, sewage disposal, school district administration, fire
and police protection, services in aid of disadvantaged or minority groups,
judicial districts, and the proportionality constraints and gerrymandering
temptations involved in demarcating electoral districts.
In a large
country such as the United States, virtually all national government agencies
are "decentralized" to the extent of working through a set of regional areas,
each with its administrative center. Each agency is subject to its own set of
efficiency considerations and political pressures in regard to the set of
regional areas and centers to be used; but problems of administrative
coordination and economy can become serious if the sets are all different, as
they would tend to be in the absence of any overall constraint. In 1969, the
President announced the establishment of a set of Standard Federal Regions and
centers, shown in Figure 9-3, in order to promote
greater uniformity in the location and geographic jurisdiction of federal field
offices. As of 1981, thirteen departments and agencies were using these
administrative regions. However, some thirty-three others had their own
nonconforming sets of regions and centers,2
even though the mandate requires that exemption from the use of the Standard
Federal Regions be granted only by petition. This fact reflects the extent of
differences in the geographic distributions of the clienteles served by various
components of the federal government.
Though both
homogeneous and functional regions make sense as useful groupings, they play
different roles in the spatial organization of society. This is particularly
evident in regard to the flow of trade, when homogeneous and nodal regions are
compared. The usual basis for a homogeneous region is a common exportable
output: The whole region is a surplus supply area for such an output, and
consequently its various parts have little or no reason to trade extensively
with one another. By contrast, in the nodal region, internal exchange of goods
and services is the very raison dêtre of the region.
Typically, there is a single main nucleus (the principal city of the region),
perhaps some subordinate centers, and the rural remainder of the territory.
These two or three specialized parts of the organism complement one another and
are linked by internal transfer media.
Our main
concern in this chapter is with functional regions and, in particular, nodal
regions. We shall begin by presenting a simple example of the kind of
statistical analysis often used to identify functional regions. Next, we shall
look more closely into the nature of the interdependence relationships that
link up a regions activities. These relationships will provide a basis
for explorations in later chapters as to (1) how regions develop and acquire
their distinctive characteristics; and (2) how a region interacts with other
areas in terms of trade, investment, migration, and other flows and
influences.
9.2
DELIMITING FUNCTIONAL REGIONS
As mentioned above,
movements of goods and services, people and money flows, and the frequency of
telephone calls are among the best indicators of functional integration. For
this reason, empirical studies rely on these measures in efforts to delimit
regions.
Table 9-1 presents hypothetical data on dollar values
of trade flows during a year among six areas, which might be thought of as
counties of a state or other subareas of a larger whole. The numbers shown give
a picture of economic interdependence among the six areas as measured in this
single dimension (trade). Our task is to group these areas into functional
regions in such a way that trade flows among areas within each region are
relatively strong, while flows between regions are relatively weak.
Clearly we
should not group areas together simply on the basis of the absolute amount of
trade between them. We can get a more meaningful measure of interarea trade
linkage by subjecting our data to "double standardization"that is,
expressing the actual trade between two areas (in) and (n) in
relation to the total external trade (exports and imports) of both
areas.3 Perhaps the simplest linkage measure
incorporating double standardization would be
Lmn=Lnm=2(Smn + Snm) /
(Em + En + Im +
In)
where Smn and Snm are trade
flows from (m) to (n) and from (n) to (m)
respectively; Emand Enare the
total exports from (m) and (n) respectively; and Im and Inare the total imports
into (m) and (n) respectively.
The
standardized linkages for the present example are shown in Table 9-2. Note that it is necessary to present only
one such linkage for each pair of areas, since Lmnis
equivalent to Lnm.
The
linkages in Table 9-2 can be used to group the six
areas into regions. The five largest Ls fully characterize the strength
of trade interactions among the six areas. In order to demonstrate this, the
five largest Ls (L62 =.366, L51 =.351, L31 =.333, L42 =.272, and L52 =.216) are used to
generate the hierarchical display known as a tree diagram (dendrogram), which is shown in Figure 9-4.
Areas 6 and
2 are joined at a linkage of .366 (L62 =.366) by connecting the lines or
"branches" associated with these areas. Similarly, the branch associated with
area 4 is connected with areas 6 and 2 at a linkage of .272, because of the
degree of interdependence represented by the standardized linkage L42 (=.272). Continuing
in this manner, we find that the branches of areas 5 and 1 are joined at a
linkage of .351 and that this pair is joined by the branch associated with area
3 at a linkage of .333.
The data
reveal two groups of areas that fit the definition of a functional region. The
linkages among areas 6, 2, and 4 and those among areas 5, 1, and 3 are
relatively strong; each group constitutes a region. Further, we find that these
regions are joined at a linkage of .216 (L52=.216). Thus we
have relatively strong linkages among members of each region, but the linkage
among regions is somewhat weaker.4
One
characteristic of the clusters identified by this grouping method is that not all areas within a given region need have strong pairwise linkages. For example, the second group (areas 5, 1, and 3) has strong
pairwise linkages between area 5 and area 1 (L51 =.351) and between area 3 and area 1 (L31 =.333). However, even though the direct linkage between
area 5 and area 3 is relatively weak (L53 =.199) these areas
are placed into the same cluster because each has strong linkage to area 1. Not
all clustering techniques have this characteristic. More restrictive groupings
based on the strength of all pairwise linkages can be applied.5
This
example has served to illustrate the application of a particularly simple
grouping method that can be used to delimit regions, given data on trade,
money, migration, or commuting flows among a set of areas.6 As the complexity of these techniques grows, they
become capable of identifying more subtle characteristics of spatial
interaction, including nodality.7
9.3 RELATIONS OF ACTIVITIES WITHIN A REGION
While the
previous section focused on the analysis of trade flows, functional
integration really depends on a variety of complex interdependencies. A simple
classification of relationships will be helpful here. We shall consider
separately (1) vertical relationships, (2) horizontal relationships, and (3) complementary relationships. As has been
brought out in previous discussion, the locational relation between two
activities can involve either mutual attraction (sometimes called a positive
linkage) or mutual repulsion.
9.3.1 Vertical Relationships
When
outputs of one activity are inputs to another activity, transfer costs are
reduced by proximity of the two activities, and the presence of either of these
activities in a region enhances to some degree the regions attractiveness
as a location for the other activity. Thus vertical linkages normally
imply mutual attraction.
Rarely,
however, is such attraction equal in both directions. We can distinguish
between cases in which the linkage is predominantly "backward" and cases in
which it is predominantly "forward."
Backward
linkage means that the mutual attraction is important mainly to the supplying activity. In other words, a market-oriented activity is
attracted by the presence of an activity to which it can sell. This is called
backward linkage because it involves transmission of an effect to an activity
further back in the sequence of operations that transforms such primary inputs
as natural resources and labor into products for final consumption.
An example
of backward linkage is the case of a Pittsburgh printing firm specializing in
the production of annual reports for large corporations. In 1968 a number of
large corporations with national headquarters in Pittsburgh were merged into
firms with headquarters in other cities, so that Pittsburgh lost its position
as the third-largest center of corporate headquarters activity. As a result,
the printing firm is reported to have lost a number of its larger contracts.
Corporations prefer to have their annual reports printed locally if possible
(in other words, the business of printing annual reports is rather closely
oriented to corporate headquarters locations).
Backward linkage is
extremely common because so much of the activity in any region is, in fact,
producing for and oriented to the regional market. The larger the region (in
terms of total area, population.. or employment), the greater the relative
importance of the internal market is likely to be. The residentiary
activities in a region (including nearly all retail and most wholesale
trade, most consumer and business services, local government services, public
utilities, construction, and the manufacturing of such perishable or bulky
products as ice cream, bread, newspapers, soft drinks, gravel, and cement
blocks) are likely to be stimulated by any increase in aggregate regional
employment and income, and thus are the recipient of backward linkage
effects.
Forward
linkage means that an impact of change is transmitted to an activity
further along in the sequence of operations. The activity affected by a forward
linkage must be locationally sensitive to the price or supply of its inputs
(that is, input-oriented). One class of forward linkage involves activities
that use by-products of other activities in the same region: for example, glue
or fertilizer factories or tanneries in areas where there is a large amount of
activity in fish canning, freezing, or meat packing. The supply of by-products
from coke ovens is similarly an inducement to establish a considerable range of
chemical processes in steel-making centerssometimes, but not necessarily,
by the same firm that operates the coke ovens. The presence of steel rolling
and finishing facilities is usually regarded as a significant factor in the
choice of location for heavy metal-fabricating industries, since it means
cheaper steel and probably quicker service.
In
addition, many of the external economies of agglomeration, discussed in Chapter 5, involve the locational advantages of a
local supply of some inputssuch as materials, supplies, equipment repair
or rental services, or last but not least, specialized manpower. The importance
of a good local supply of business services for regional growth, and
particularly for the establishment of new lines of activity in a region, has
become increasingly recognized in recent years.8 There has also been marked emphasis on the vital role of infrastructure (the supply of basic public facilities and services) in
the development of backward, low-income regions, both in the United States and
overseas. In all these situations, forward linkages are the key factors.
9.3.2 Horizontal Relationships
The role of horizontal relationships has already been discussed in some detail in Chapter 4. These relationships involve the
competition of activities, or units of activity, for either markets or inputs.
The locational effect is basically one of mutual repulsion, in contrast to the
mutual attraction implied in vertical linkages.
Particularly significant for regional growth and development is the
rivalry of different activities for scarce and not easily expansible local
resources (such as particular varieties of labor, sites on riverbanks or with a
view, clean and cool water, or clean air). The entrance of a new activity using
such local resources tends to raise their costs and may thus hamper or even
preclude other activities requiring the same resources. The region as a whole
has much at stake in this rivalry. A relevant and important question of
regional policy, for example, is whether to let the regions water and
waterside sites be preempted and polluted by water-using industries or to
reserve them in part for residential institutional, or recreational use. Again,
should regional efforts to enhance employment opportunities take the form of
trying to attract new activities with the largest number of jobs, regardless of
character, or should priority be given to new activities that pay high wages,
provide opportunities for individual learning and advancement, and attract a
superior grade of in-migrants? Should a communitys last remaining tract
of vacant level land be given over to an airport, a strip-mining operation, a
high-class low-density suburban development, a low-income housing project, a
missile-launching site, or an industrial park? How much smoke is the community
willing to tolerate for the sake of the income earned by the smoke producers
and the taxes they pay? These are all familiar issues that must be faced by
citizens, responsible authorities, and planners of a city or larger region; and
they all arise because of horizontal linkage in the form of competition for
scarce local resources. Regional objectives and policy are the subject of Chapter 12.
9.3.3 Complementary Relationships
We have
already noted, in previous chapters, complementary relationships among
activities in a region, particularly in connection with external economies in Chapter 5. The locational effect is mutual
attractionthat is, an increase of one activity in a region encourages the
growth of a complementary activity.
Mutual Attraction Among Suppliers of Complementary
Products.Examples of this attraction are found in fashion goods and
other shopping goods industries. As additional producers come into a region,
they help those already there by building up the regions status as a
Mecca for buyers of those products or services, because the buyer is looking
for a variety of offerings and a chance to compare and shop around. The
manufacture of sportswear in some large cities in California and Texas in
recent years has developed largely on this basis.
This is
really a two-step linkage, which can be broken down into (1) a forward linkage
effect, whereby the coming of an additional producer attracts to the region
more buyers of the product, and (2) a backward linkage effect, whereby the
greater demand from those buyers enhances the attractiveness of the region for
still more producers.
Such
effects are, however, not entirely restricted to shopping goods. Still another
example from the Pittsburgh region is pertinent here. In the 1960s, various
civic leaders urged Pittsburgh to aim for major league status as a designer and
producer of urban transit systems to meet the projected growing demand from
large urban areas in the United States and other countries. A wide variety of
inputs is needed to feed into this line of activity: the manufacture of
components and supplies, designers knowledgeable in transport technology and
urban planning, urban and regional economists, and specialized research
facilities and consultants. Had the main effort been successful and had
Pittsburgh firms received more orders for transit systems, local suppliers of
the various inputs cited above would have flourished and multiplied, and their
availability and expertise would have enhanced further the capabilities and
reputation of the prime contractors.
Mutual Attraction Among Users of Jointly Supplied Products. This second kind of complementary linkage (also with an effect of mutual
locational attraction) is basically the converse of the complementary linkage
just discussed. Many activities (perhaps most) turn out not one but several
different products, those of lesser importance or value being called
by-products. A regional activity that furnishes a market for one or more
by-products helps the supplying activity, and this can make the suppliers
other outputs more easily or cheaply available to some third activity which
uses them. All three of the activities are then in a situation of mutual
assistance and attraction.
There are
many examples of this effect in the chemical industries, which by their nature
usually turn out combinations of products. Producers of coke for blast furnaces
also turn out gas and a variety of hydrocarbon chemicals that can serve as
building blocks for a still wider range of products, such as synthetic rubber,
synthetic gasoline, dyestuffs, and pharmaceuticals. The presence in the same
region of industries using any of the first-stage outputs of the coal
distillation process enhances the returns of the coke producer and may even be
a significant factor in its decisions to expand or relocate. If it does expand
output, this means a still larger (and perhaps cheaper and more dependable)
regional supply of other coal distillation products, which in turn makes the
region more attractive as a location for industries using these
products.
Like the
complementary linkage among sellers of jointly demanded products, discussed
earlier, this complementary linkage can be broken down into two separate links.
There is a backward linkage effect if additional demand from a new synthetic
rubber producer, for example, leads coke producers to expand their output. Then
there is a forward linkage if the resulting increased regional supply of coal
distillation products from the ovens attracts still other users of these
products (for example, producers of pharmaceuticals or dyestuffs) to the
region.
In case the
reader is by now a bit bemused with the nomenclature of linkages, some surcease
is provided in Figure 9-5, where the linkages are all
schematically diagrammed and illustrated.
The
complementary linkages we have described are, of course, valid regardless of
whether the complementary processes are engaged in by separate firms or within
the same firm. In the case of the steel producer and its coke ovens, for
example, the firm may elect to process its distillation outputs for one or more
additional stages or even down to the final consumer product, rather than
selling them to other firms.
Complementary Linkages and the Economies of Scale and
Agglomeration. The external economies of agglomeration, discussed in
Chapter 5, represent in part complementary linkages among users of jointly
supplied products. Manufacturers of fashion garments and many other typical
external-economy industries identified by Lichtenberg (see Section 5.3.3 above) have a strong tendency
to cluster because they draw on both kinds of complementary linkage: among
suppliers of complementary products and among users of jointly supplied
products. For example, fashion garment manufacturers find a clustered location
pattern profitable (1) because such clustering gives the location the advantage
of variety of offerings, which attracts buyers, and (2) because in such a
cluster many kinds of inputs can be secured quickly and cheaply from
specialized suppliers who could not economically exist without the volume
supported by a large cluster. We see, then, that external economies of
agglomeration can be broken down into internal economies of scale plus two
kinds of complementary linkage; each of which, in turn, can be broken down into
backward and forward linkages.
9.4 REGIONAL SPECIALIZATION
The growth
of a region and the kinds of opportunities it provides for its residents depend
to a large extent on the regions mix of activities. We can characterize
regions as being more or less narrowly specialized in a limited range of
activities, or as being more or less diversified or "well rounded."
9.4.1 A Classification of U.S. Metropolitan Regions
To
illustrate this differentiation, let us consider the metropolitan areas of the
United States as separate urban regions. Table 9-3 shows a structural grouping made by the U.S. Department of Commerce on the
basis of the sources of income of residents of each SMSA in 1966.
"Manufacturing" SMSAs (there were 97 in all) were defined as those in which
earnings from manufacturing employment accounted for a relatively high fraction
of total personal income. In each of the 28 SMSAs in the
"manufacturing-intensive" category, this fraction was 40 percent or higher.
Nearly all of those 28 are in the Mideast and Great Lakes regions.9
SMSAs with
at least 20 percent of personal income derived from government (compared with
12.4 percent for all SMSAs) were put in the "government" category. In 26 of
these, military payrolls bulked large (at least 10 percent of personal income);
in the other 21, government civilian payrolls were relatively more
important.
There were
10 SMSAs classified as agricultural, since each had at least 10 percent of its
personal income (that is, more than the average for all nonmetropolitan areas!)
derived from agriculture. This classification reflects the fact that SMSAs,
being generally made up of whole counties, contain substantial amounts of rural
farm territory, usually intensively developed.
In 5 SMSAs,
mining was a major source of personal income. In 4 of thesein Texas,
Oklahoma, and Louisianathe specialization was in oil and natural gas
production, and property incomes also bulked large in their sources of income;
the fifth was the Duluth-Superior SMSA, specializing in iron ore
mining.
Recreational and retirement SMSAs (there were 4 of each) were
characterized by low proportions of income derived from manufacturing, rather
high proportions derived from property, and (in the case of the retirement
SMSAs such as Tampa-St. Petersburg and Tucson) high proportions of income
derived from transfer payments, principally pensions.
There were
16 SMSAs classed as regional or national centers because an above-average share
of their incomes was derived from typically residentiary types of activity.
This reflects the fact that in such areas, some of the typical residentiary
activities such as transportation, communications, finance, trade, and services
are really export activities serving an unusually far-flung region. The 4
national centers were New York, Los Angeles, Chicago, and San Francisco,
ranking first, second, third, and sixth in population in 1966. It is
interesting to observe that Philadelphia and Boston (ranking fourth and fifth
in size) did not appear as national centers; because they are so close to New
York, their areas of influence are curtailed.
The
residual group of 40 "mixed" SMSAs comprises those lacking any of the marked
specializations of structure that characterize the other categories.
In similar
fashion, larger geographical areas such as states or multistate regions exhibit
different specializations of function and structure. Regional specialization in
some specific activity generally implies that the region is a net exporter of
the product of that activity, although in some cases it can reflect instead a
distinctive pattern of demand in the region itself. Thus Michigans
specialization in motor vehicle production and the District of Columbias
specialization in government are associated with heavy exports of cars and
government services from those areas; but the unusually high proportions of
health and recreational service activities in retirement areas are primarily
accounted for by the local demand.
9.4.2
Some Quantitative Measures of Specialization and Concentration
The location quotient has already been introduced in Appendix 8-2 and further discussed above
in section 9.4.1. As we have seen, (1) the same quotient
measures both the degree of an areas specialization in an activity and
the degree of concentration of the activity in the area; (2) the quotient can
be calculated in three ways, with identical results; and (3) the quotient can
be based on either just one variable, such as employment, in the areas and
activities involved, or on two different variables, such as earnings in a given
activity and total employment, population, or income.
In still
other applications, we might want to compare the location quotient for the same
activity and area at two different dates in order to measure change in
specialization or concentration. Finally, we can apply the quotient not to an
activity but to some other measurable characteristic of an area (such as the
size of a specified ethnic group, number of motorcycles registered, or number
of dog licenses issued) as related to some different characteristic of activity
such as population or employment.
The coefficient of specialization, a broader type of measure, can be used to
gauge the degree to which the mix of a regions economy differs from some
standard, such as the mix in the national economy or the mix in the same region
at an earlier date. The calculation of this measure is illustrated in Table 9-4.
The first
two columns of numbers are the percentage distributions of value added by
manufacture in 1978 according to broad industry groups in the United States and
New England respectively, and the last two columns contain the differences
between the national and the New England percentages. If the industrial mix in
New England were identical to the national mix (that is, if New England had
just the same share of the national total in every industry group), all these
differences would be zero.
The sum of
the-differences is in any case zero, since the pluses exactly offset the
minuses. But if we add up just the positive differences (or just the negative
ones, which would give the same sum) we have a measure of the degree to which
the New England mix differs from the national. This is the coefficient of
specialization. A coefficient of zero indicates no specialization at all, with
the regions mix just matching the national or other standard mix. The
maximum value of the coefficient would be close to 100 percent and would
correspond to a situation in which the region in question is devoted entirely
to one industry not present in any other region.
This
coefficient, too, has a fairly wide range of applications. For example, we
could use it to determine which areas most nearly have a cross section of the
national population in terms of age groups or ethnic categories; or whether a
given regions employment pattern diverges more from the national pattern
in years of recession than in prosperous years; or whether two areas are more
like each other than either is like some third area (which might be useful in
aggregating areas into regions on the basis of homogeneity).
Finally, one other closely
related measure should be mentioned: the coefficient of concentration, which measures how closely one locational distribution (for example, that
of population, income, or employment in a specific activity) matches another
locational distribution (for example, that of total employment or land area).
Thus if the distribution of population by counties in the United States just
matched the distribution of land area among counties, we should say that the
population was evenly distributed (at the county level); while if the location
pattern of the rubber industry is radically different from that of population
or total employment, we can say that the rubber industry is spatially
concentrated.
The
coefficient of concentration is calculated in much the same way as the
coefficient of specialization, except that we line up two columns of figures
representing location patterns (that is, each is a percentage
distribution by areas), take all the positive or all the negative differences,
and add.
Although
location quotients and coefficients of concentration and specialization are
handy summary measures, their limitations must be kept in mind. In particular,
their values depend partly on the arbitrary decisions we make regarding
demarcation of both activities and areas. The measures all become larger if we
use smaller geographical units (for example, states instead of Census
divisions, or counties instead of states, or Census tracts instead of cities),
and they become larger also if we employ a more detailed classification of
activities. Consequently, any two coefficients of the same type are comparable
only if they are based on the same classifications.
9.5 SUMMARY
A region is
an area that is usefully considered as an entity for purposes of description,
analysis, administration, planning, or policy. It can be demarcated on the
basis of internal homogeneity or functional integration. Nodal regions are
those where the character of functional integration is such that a single
specialized urban nucleus can be identified. Homogeneity and nodality are basic
even when political, historical, military, or other considerations are
importantly involved in regional demarcation.
Functional
regions may be delimited by various statistical techniques. Some of these rely
on data concerning commodity, service, financial, migration, or commuting flows
among regions in order to identify the strength of interdependencies between
and within regions.
Activities
within a region interact in various ways. Horizontal linkages involve basically
competition among similar units and are expressed in mutual spatial repulsion,
with formation of market areas and/or supply areas. Vertical linkages (between
the two parties in a transaction, such as seller and buyer) involve spatial
attraction to save transfer costs. If it is primarily the buyers who are
attracted toward the sellers, a vertical linkage is called forward; whereas
backward linkage means that the sellers are attracted toward the buyers.
Complementary linkages, more complex in nature, entail mutual attraction among
(1) suppliers of complementary products or (2) users of jointly supplied
products. Such complementary linkages are basic to the external economies of
agglomeration discussed in Chapter 5.
Not only
homogeneous regions but also functional ones tend to develop distinctive
specializations of activities or other characteristics. The nature and degree
of specialization can be gauged by such statistical measures as the location
quotient and the coefficients of (area) specialization and (activity)
concentration.
TECHNICAL TERMS INTRODUCED IN THIS CHAPTER |
Homogeneous
region |
Residentiary
activities |
Functional
integration |
Forward
linkage |
Functional
region |
Infrastructure |
Nodal
region |
Horizontal
linkage |
Positive
linkage |
Complementary
linkage |
Vertical
linkage |
Coefficient of
specialization |
Backward
linkage |
Coefficient of
concentration |
SELECTED
READINGS
Lawrence A. Brown and John
Holmes, "The Delimitation of Functional Regions, Nodal Regions, and Hierarchies
by Functional Distance Approaches," Journal of Regional Science, 11, 1
(April 1971), 57-72.
Beverly Duncan and Stanley
Lieberson, Metropolis and Region in Transition (Beverly Hills, Calif.:
Sage Publications, 1970).
Otis Dudley Duncan et al., Metropolis and Region (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press,
1960).
David L. Huff, "The
Delineation of a National System of Planning Regions on the Basis of Urban
Spheres of Influence," Regional Studies, 7, 3 (September 1973),
323-329.
W. F. Lever, "Industrial
Movement, Spatial Association, and Functional Linkages," Regional Studies, 6, 4 (December 1972), 371-384.
Harry W. Richardson, Regional Economics (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1978), Chapter
1.
ENDNOTES
1. Lawrence A. Brown and John Holmes, "The Delimitation of Functional
Regions, Nodal Regions, and Hierarchies by Functional Distance Approaches," Journal of Regional Science, 11, 1 (April 1971), p. 58.
2. See General Services Agency, Office of the Federal Register, The United States Directory of Federal Regional Structure, 1981/1982 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1981).
3. Standardization can be accomplished by any of several techniques.
For example, Paul B. Slater has developed a technique that constrains each row
and each column total to unity or some other number. The resultant matrix of
flows is thus doubly standardized by one transformation. See P. B.
Slater and H. P. M. Winchester, "Clustering and Scaling of Transaction Flow
Tables: A French Interdepartmental Migration Example," IEEE Transactions on
Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, SMC-8 (August 1978), 635-640; and P. B.
Slater and Wolfgang Schwarz, "Global Trade Patterns: Scaling and Clustering
Analysis," IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, SMC-9
(July 1979), 381-387. The algorithm used in these studies is available in SAS (Statistical Analysis System) Supplemental Library Users Guide (Cary, N.C.: SAS Institute, 1980) under the name IPFPHC.
4. When clustering methods of the sort described in the example are
applied to actual data, areas that have rather diffuse linkages (those that
interact with most other areas in a uniform manner) often stand out as being
isolated or unconnected to any particular group in a clear way.
Paradoxically, areas of this sort tend to be either very remote (like Alaska in
the U.S.) or high-order central places (like Paris, France). In the first
instance, difficulty of access and in the second, centrality results in
dispersed interactions with other areas.
5. For an excellent survey of related statistical techniques, see
Michael R. Anderberg, Cluster Analysis for Applications (New York:
Academic Press, 1973). The interested reader will also find a number of
computer programs, which have been developed for this type of data analysis, in
the same source.
6. Migration data are used frequently for this purpose because of the
availability of regularly published information on place-to-place movements.
However, while migration between two areas is certainly indicative of labor
market interactions, the areas in question may have very limited linkages in
other dimensions (trade, for example). Indeed, as we shall find in Chapter 10, the fact that there is substantial
migration between two areas may result from the fact that the two economies are
quite diverse, reacting to different stimuli or being affected differently by
the same stimuli, so that the correlation in their behavior may actually be
negative.
7. Applying quite different methods from the one described above,
a number of researchers have devised sophisticated techniques for carving up a
country into "optimum" sets of nodal regions on the basis of weighted factors
of spatial linkage. The formula can be adjusted to produce demarcations of any
desired fineness or coarseness. For such demarcations, dividing the United
States successively into 72, 292, and 347 areas, see David L. Huff, "The
Delineation of a National System of Planning Regions on the Basis of Urban
Spheres of Influence," Regional Studies, 7, 3 (September 1973), 323-329.
See also the discussion in section
12.6.3 concerning the work of Karl Fox and Brian Berry in demarcating
efficient regions for planning, development, and administrative
purposes.
8. See Benjamin Chinitz, "Contrasts in Agglomeration: New York and
Pittsburgh," Papers and Proceedings of the American Economic Association, 51 (May 1961), 279-289. Chinitz argues that a center such as Pittsburgh,
heavily specialized in a few industries and dominated by large plants and
firms, is likely to be deficient in various business services needed by small
and new firms, because the dominant firms are big enough to provide such
services internally for themselves.
9. The basis on which SMSAs were characterized according to the
primary specialization for Table 9-3 will be
recognized as essentially the same as the location quotient procedure already
described in Appendix 8-2. For example,
if in a given SMSA the fraction of total personal income derived from
manufacturing employment was notably large compared to that fraction for all
SMSAs, that SMSAs location quotient was much greater than 1 in
manufacturing. Other location quotients for the same SMSA would measure its
degree of specialization in other kinds of activity; and the SMSA could be
categorized according to the activity in which it had the highest location
quotient, It will be observed that the calculations here were in terms of
earnings as related to income, whereas in the application of location quotients
described in Appendix 8-2, they were in
terms of employment as related to employment.