10.1 INTRODUCTION
The
importance of manpower supply as a location factor is suggested by the sheer
magnitude of labor costs as an element in the total outlays of productive
enterprises. In the United States, wage and salary payments, and supplements
thereto, account for about three-fourths of the national income, and this does
not include the earnings of self-employed people and business proprietors (for
example, farmers, store owners, and free-lance professionals), which mainly
represent a return to their labor. Accordingly, we should expect to find many
kinds of activities locationally sensitive to the differentials in the
availability, price, and quality of labor.
Labors role as a purchased input, however, is only one aspect
of the locational interdependence of people and their economic activities.
People in their role as consumers of the final output of goods and services
affect the locational choices of market-oriented activities. They play still
another role as users of residential land; and in urban areas, residence is by
far the largest land use. Finally, and most important, the purpose of the whole
economic system is to provide a livelihood for people. Regional economics is
vitally concerned with regional income differences, the opportunities found in
different types of communities, and regional population growth and
migration.
The present
chapter is devoted to integrating and exploring these various aspects of "the
location of people." We begin by considering the locational differences in the
rewards or "price" of labor.
10.2 A LOOK AT SOME DIFFERENTIALS
Comparing
wages or incomes among different areas is not as straightforward a matter as it
might appear, even when appropriate data are at hand. It is a question of what
comparison is relevant to the question we have in mind. For example, if we want
to gauge the relative opulence of two communities (perhaps as an indication of
how rich a market each would provide for consumer goods and services), then
average personal income in dollars per family or per person would be
appropriate to compare. But an individual looking for an area where his work
will be well rewarded would do better to compare real earnings in his or
her occupational category; that is, monetary earnings deflated by a
cost-of-living index. Finally, an employer looking for a good labor supply
location would be most interested in comparisons of labor cost, based on
monetary wage-and-salary rates adjusted for labor productivity and fringe
benefits. The relevance of such different measures should be kept in mind as we
look at the data.
10.2.1
Differentials in Pay Levels
Rates of
pay in any specific occupation can differ widely from one place to another and
even within the same labor market area. For example, in 1978 the union hourly
wage scale for laborers and helpers in the building trades averaged $8.54 for
65 cities surveyed by the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, with the rate in
individual cities ranging from a high of $10.54 in Cleveland, Ohio, to a low of
$5.21 in Huntsville, Alabama.1
The
differentials among regions are not entirely erratic. Some evidence of an
underlying pattern appears in Table 10-1, in which the labor markets are
classified by broad region and by size. In each of the three broad occupational
categories, the South shows up as the region with the lowest pay levels. The
West and North Central regions pay generally higher rates. In addition, with
the exception of two occupational categories in the North Central region, there
is a tendency for rates to be higher in the larger metropolitan areas. Finally,
it can be noted that the interregional disparities are wider for unskilled
workers than for the other groups. This feature of the pattern will be
explained later.
Although
the figures cited are based on careful comparisons of the standard earnings
rate in (as nearly as possible) identical jobs, they do not give a complete
picture of relative advantages for either the employee or the employer. No
account is taken of the increasingly important fringe benefits (vacations,
overtime pay, sick leave, pensions, and so on) or of differences in the cost of
living. Nor do these comparisons give us any indication of differentials in the
productivity of workers, which also play a part in determining the
employers labor cost per unit of output.
10.2.2
Income Differentials
Income
differentials also show a discernible pattern according to region and size of
urban place. But the difference in per capita or per family incomes between two
areas is, of course, determined not only by relative earnings levels in
specific occupations but also by differences in the occupational and industry
mix of the areas, the degree of labor force participation, and unemployment
rates. For example, regional per capita personal income in 1981 varied as shown
in Table 10-2.
The
relation of income level to type of urban or rural place of residence is shown
in Table 10-3. We observe there that in 1980, incomes were higher in
metropolitan areas than in nonmetropolitan areas; higher in larger metropolitan
areas than in smaller metropolitan areas; higher outside central cities than
inside of central cities; and higher in nonfarm rural areas than on
farms.
10.2.3 Differentials in Living Costs and Real
Income
From the
standpoint of the worker, the possible advantage of working in a high-wage or
high-income area depends partly on how expensive it is to live there. Most of
us are aware that there are considerable differences in the cost of living in
different parts of the country and different sizes of community.
Although it
is impossible to measure relative living costs comprehensively so as to take
into account all the needs and preferences of an individual, a useful
indication is provided by surveys of the comparative cost, in different
locations, of securing a specific "standard family budget" of goods and
services. Table 10-4 summarizes the findings of a
survey of this type. A fairly distinct pattern of differentials appears. With
few exceptions, living costs are higher in metropolitan areas than in
nonmetropolitan areas for major kinds of expenditure. When one looks at total
family consumption, living costs in the South are clearly lower than elsewhere
in both metropolitan and nonmetropolitan areas. This is attributable to the
comparatively low cost of housing and food in the South. Also, examination of
the indices for individual SMSAs reported in the survey suggests that high
housing costs are associated with large city size, rapid recent growth, and
rigorous climate.
A study of
SMSA characteristics associated with living cost for low-, moderate-, and
high-income families in 38 SMSAs, using regression analysis, found that 64
percent of the total variance in living costs for moderate- and high-income
families could be explained in terms of three significant variables:
population, location in the Southeast or elsewhere, and the degree to which
spatial expansion of the urban area was subject to "topological and physical
constraints" (for example, water or mountain barriers) on its periphery. This
last factor could be expected to influence travel distances and costs and also
land cost. Climate did not show up as a significantly correlated
characteristic, nor did size of place in the case of low-income
families.2
A crude
picture of differentials in real incomes among metropolitan areas can be
obtained by dividing the per capita personal income for each area by the index
of consumer budget costs for the same area.3For
the sample of metropolitan areas on which Table 10-4 is based, the real income
index so obtained is rather well correlated with per capita personal money
income, while per capita personal money income is somewhat less strongly
correlated with the index of consumer budget costs.
Thus living
costs tend to be high where money incomes are high (not surprisingly, in view
of the important impact of service costs and other local labor costs on the
consumer budget). But the interarea differentials seem to be wider for money
incomes than for budget costs; so real income thus estimated is a little higher
in places where money income is high. By the same token, interarea
differentials in real income are much smaller than those in money
income.
There is
evidence that similar relationships prevail also when we compare different size
classes of places,4though it is impossible to
compare adequately the psychic satisfactions and costs that come from living in
large cities as against smaller places.
10.3 THE SUPPLY OF LABOR AT A LOCATION
In trying
to understand the causes and effects of wage and income differentials, it is
useful to consider separately the supply and demand sides of the local labor
market. The aggregate supply of labor in a community may be quite inelastic in
the short run, since it can change only through migration or changes in labor
force participation. For a single activity or occupation within the labor
market area, the supply is more elastic because it can be affected by workers
changing their activities or occupations as well as by migration and changes in
the labor force. The labor supply as seen by an individual employer is still
more elastic, and for small employers in a large labor market almost perfectly
so.
10.3.1
Work Location Preferences and Labor Mobility
There are
many reasons for preferring a job in one area to the same kind of job in
another area, and the decision to move can be very complex. A systematic
evaluation of costs and benefits is in order, much as a decision-maker in
business evaluates the pros and cons of an investment. Thus the potential
migrant would want to recognize what he or she would be giving up (the
opportunity costs of the move) and make a good guess about what would lie in
store in the new location.
Neither of
these tasks is particularly easy, and a number of considerations would have to
be recognized. First, it is not adequate to compare only basic wages; all
fringe benefits must be considered as well. Also, for an increasingly large
share of the work force, the employment prospects of the spouse may be as
important as that of the "primary" wage earner.5 Second, a community with cheaper living costs might be preferred in the absence
of any pay differential. Third, various aspects of the quality of the job, such
as security and prospects of advancement, may be considered. Expected growth in
earnings some years down the road may be an important factor in the decision to
act now.6 Finally, other aspects of the
desirability of the community as a place to live can include, for example,
climate, cultural and social opportunities, and access to other places that one
might like to visit.7 Differences among places on
any of these accounts can be compared to money income differentials: How much
additional compensation is required to give up immediate access to cultural
events, or how much less would one be willing to accept in terms of earnings
for a climate that suits ones tastes?
Spatial
mobility refers to peoples propensity to change locations in response
to some measurable set of incentives, identified in practice as "real income"
or simply as money wage rates deflated by a cost-of-living index. If mobility
in this sense were perfect and real wages thus equal everywhere, there would be
differentials in money wages paralleling the differentials in living costs. A
labor market where the living costs were 10 percent above average would pay
wages 10 percent above average, but real wages there would be the same as
anywhere else.
The term equalizing differentials has been applied to this kind of money wage or
income differential.8The pattern of actual money
differentials is, then, made up of two components: (1) equalizing
differentials, which would exist even in the absence of any impediment to labor
mobility, and (2) real differentials, representing differences in real
income and thus presumably caused by impediments to mobility.
The
significance of this distinction is that workers can logically be
expected to choose locations and to move in response to real differentials; whereas employers looking for cheap labor will be
more interested in the total money wage differential, which combines
both real and equalizing differentials.
These
concepts of real and money wages, cost of living, equalizing and real
differentials, and mobility help us to understand some basic motivations of the
locational choices of employees and employers; but unfortunately they are not
very sharp tools. We have already noted the impossibility of including in
indices of income and living costs all the considerations affecting the
desirability of a place to live. For example, such indices take no account of
the attractions of a mild and sunny climate (except as reflected in housing
costs), the dirt and discomforts of life in a large industrial city, the social
pressures and cultural voids of a small town, or the advantage to a research
worker of being stationed where the action is in his or her field. As a result
of our inability to measure real income fully, we are also unable to measure
mobility in a completely unambiguous way. If a family, for example, likes the
physical and social climate of its surroundings and refrains from moving to
another area where the pay is higher both in money terms and as deflated by a
conventional family budget cost index, should we ascribe its failure to move to
a lack of mobility?
A further
difficulty with the simple concept of real and equalizing differentials is the
implication that migration is not merely motivated by real-income differentials
but tends to eliminate them. Under certain conditions it is possible for
migration, even when so motivated, to leave the differential unchanged or even
to widen it. We need to look further into both the causes and the consequences
of migration.
10.3.2
Who Migrates: Why, When, and Where?
Migration
is influenced by three conditions: the characteristics of both the origin and
destination areas, the difficulties of the journey itself, and the
characteristics of the migrant.
Reasons for Moving.It is a drastic oversimplification
to explain migration simply on the basis of response to differentials in wage
rates, income, or employment opportunity. The U.S. Bureau of the Census bases
its tabulations of migration on changes in residence. Since some of these are
local (moves within the same county) and others involve substantial distance
(intercounty moves), one would expect reasons for moving to differ
widely.
Those
persons who move only within the same county are predominantly influenced by
housing considerations. Since all of a county is generally regarded as being
included within a single labor market or commuting range, job changes are
related only to a minor extent with intracounty moves. Most such movers are not
changing jobs.
For those
who move to a different county the picture is quite different, with employment
changes (including entry to or exit from military service) emerging as the
major reasons for migrating. This reflects the fact that an intercounty
migration generally involves shifting to a different labor market beyond the
commuting range for the former job. A change of residence is involved but is
not the primary motivation.
Characteristics of Origin and Destination Areas. The
characteristics most obviously affecting attractiveness to the individual
migrant have already been suggested. In addition, we should expect that a
larger place would have more migrants arriving and departing than a smaller
place, more or less in proportion to size. But size itself can significantly
affect the appeal of a place for the individual. Historically, migrants have
responded to the greater variety of job opportunities in larger urban places
and their suburbs by migrating to them in numbers somewhat more than
proportional to their size.
Rather than
thinking of migration as being motivated simply by net advantages of some
places over others, it is useful to separate the pull of attractive
characteristics from the push of unattractive ones. Clearly, many people
migrate because they do not like it where they are, or perhaps are even being
forced out by economic, political, or social pressures. The basic decision is
to get out, and the choice of a particular place to migrate to is a secondary
and subsequent decision, involving a somewhat different set of considerations.
On the other hand, some areas can be so generally attractive as to pull
migrants from a wide variety of other locations, including many who were
reasonably well satisfied where they were.9
Recent
studies on migration using detailed data on flows in both directions (rather
than just net flows) have considerably revised earlier notions of push and
pull. Rather surprisingly, it appears that in most cases the so-called push
factor explaining out-migration from an area is not primarily the economic
characteristics of the area (such as low wages or high unemployment) but the
demographic characteristics of the population of the area. Areas with a high
proportion of well-educated young adults have high rates of out-migration,
regardless of local economic opportunity. The pull factor (that is, the
migrants choice of where to go) is, however, primarily a matter of the
economic characteristics of areas. Migration is consistently heavier into
prosperous areas. Accordingly, the observed net migration losses of depressed
areas generally reflect low in-migration but not high out-migration, and the
net migration gains of prosperous areas reflect high in-migration rather than
low out-migration.10
Difficulties of the Journey. Within a country, distance
is perhaps the most obviously significant characteristic of the migration
journey, and virtually all analyses of migration flows have evaluated the
extent to which migration streams attenuate with longer distance. Thus a simple
"gravity model" of migration posits that the annual net migration from A to B will be proportional to the populations of A and B and to the size of some differential (say, in wage rates) between A and B, and inversely proportional to the square of the distance from A to B, as follows:
(where the
Ps represent populations, the Ws wage rates, D the distance, M the number of migrants per unit of time, and g a constant with a
value depending on what units are used for the variables).11 This basic migration flow model has been statistically
tested and modified in many ways in the attempt to make it more realistic. It
has already been suggested that in many circumstances at least, there is a
"scale effect" upon migration, which can be incorporated in the model by giving
the populations an exponent greater than 1. Any relevant factor of differential
advantage that can be quantified (for example, unemployment rates, mean summer
or winter temperature, percentage of sunny days, average education or income
level of the population, percentage of housing in good condition, crime rates,
insurance rates, or air pollution) can be introduced, with whatever relative
weighting the user of the model deems appropriate.
The
distance factor in the model likewise can be assigned a different exponent to
fit the circumstances (there is nothing special about the square of the
distance, except for the law of physical gravitation) and elaborated in
various ways. Actually, distance per se is at best only loosely related to the
difficulties attending migration. The factors involved are actual moving costs
(which can sometimes be the least important obstacle), uncertainty, risk and
investment of time involved (including that associated with acquiring
information), restrictions on migration per Se, and what is sometimes called social distancesuggesting the degree of difficulty the migrant may
have in making adequate social adjustment after he or she arrives.12 As an example of this last factor, a model designed by
W. H. Somermeijer to explain Dutch internal migration flows included a term
that measured the difference in the Catholic-Protestant ratio between the two
areas. Introduction of this term substantially improved the models
explanatory power, suggesting that members of each religious persuasion tend to
move mainly to areas where their coreligionists predominate. 13
Social
distance depends partly, of course, on the individual migrant. But wide social
distances between communities and regions (that is, great heterogeneity) tend
to restrict migration flows to those individuals who can most easily make the
required adjustment. With the improvement in communications and travel, social
distance in space tends to lessen; but it is still a factor, for example,
between French and English Canada, between the North and the Deep South in the
United States, or between farm and city.14
Another
feature of migration paths is that they seem to be subject to economies of
volume of traffic along any one route. Well-beaten paths become increasingly
easy and popular for successive migrants. This is so for a variety of reasons.
Sometimes (as in the case of earlier transoceanic and more recent Puerto
Rico-to-mainland migrant travel) transport agencies have given special rates or
in other ways have favored the increase of migrant travel on the most
frequented routes. Perhaps more generally applicable and more important is the
fact that migrants try to minimize uncertainties and risks by choosing places
about which they have at least a little information and where they will find
relatives, friends, or others from their home areas who will help them to gain
a foothold.15 This tendency is particularly
important, of course, when the social distance is large. It goes far to explain
the heavy concentration of late-nineteenth-century European migrants to the
United States in a few large cities, and the even more remarkable concentration
of particular ethnic and sub-ethnic groups in certain cities and neighborhoods,
which even now retain unto the third generation some of their special
character. The most recent ethnically distinctive waves of migration to
American citiesthose of blacks, Puerto Ricans, and Chicanoshave in
the same fashion followed a few well-beaten paths. For example, it has been
established that Southern black migrants to Chicago came mainly from certain
sections of the South, while those going to Washington, D.C., or Baltimore
originated in other Southern areas, and those going to the West Coast in still
other areas. Recent migrants from the Caribbean (other than those from Puerto
Rico) remain highly concentrated in the Miami area.
An analysis
of labor mobility in the United States between 1957 and 1960, based on Social
Security records, gives striking evidence of the beaten-path effect where migration of blacks is concerned. For white workers, both male and
female, migration flows were significantly related to earnings differentials
(positively) and to distance (negatively) as we might expect. For black men,
however (and to a lesser extent for black women), earnings differentials and
distance appeared to be less important determinants than either the number of
blacks or the proportion of blacks in the work force of the destination area.
In other words, blacks (or at any rate, black males) were selectively attracted
to labor markets in which there already was a high proportion of blacks.16
The
tendency of migration to channelize in well-beaten paths provides part of the
explanation for another characteristic of migration streams already mentioned;
namely, that places with high rates of inward migration tend to have high rates
of outward migration as well. This so-called counterstream effect was
noted as long ago as the 1880s in E. G. Ravensteins pioneer statement of
migration principles, and has been amply verified since.17
The point
here is that a well-beaten path eases travel in both directions.
Migrants generally come to a place with incomplete knowledge, and many of the
disappointed ones simply retrace their steps. Also, a city that offers
especially favorable adjustment opportunities for migrants is likely to serve
as a "port of entry" for migrants coming into that region or country. New York
has historically been the entry place for transatlantic immigrants, and Chicago
has functioned as an important first destination for Mexicans migrating to the
American Midwest. In such cases, many of the migrants move out again (either to
other places in the region or perhaps back to their place of origin), so the
out-migration rate of such an entry point or staging area is likely to be high.
More generally, it is plausible to assume that people who have just migrated
are especially mobile by circumstances or taste and hence more likely than
others to swell the outward flow.
Migration
flows over long distances within the same country have historically involved a
considerable amount of what is sometimes called chain migration. Most of
the migrants move relatively short distances, but the moves are predominantly
in one direction, forming a stream. As people move from B to A, they are replaced in B by migrants from C, who in turn are
replaced by migrants from D. It has been established that most of the
massive redistribution of population in England during the Industrial
Revolution was carried out in such fashion by short-distance moves cumulating
toward the new industrial towns.18
Characteristics of the Migrant. Migration is basically selective. Some people are far more prone to migrate than are others.
This is often expressed as a difference in the mobility of different groups,
but we really cannot explain all of the difference in that way, since the incentives to migrate are not the same. For example, a young scientist
fresh out of school is confronted with a quite different set of pushes and
pulls than an aging farmer, an established business executive, a manual
laborer, or a wealthy widow.
The most
conspicuous differences in migration rates are those experienced by the
individual in passing through successive stages of a lifetime. These changes
are (as shown in Figure 10-1) rather similar for the
two sexes; for simplicitys sake we describe them here in male
terms.
A very
young child is relatively portable. After he enters school and has older, more
settled parents and probably more brothers or sisters, his probability of
moving declines. The rate rises suddenly when he is ready to look for a job or
choose a college, and it remains high until after he is married and has
children of his own. As his stake in his job and community grows, and as his
and his familys other local ties develop, he becomes less and less likely
to move. His mobility recovers somewhat at the stage when all of his children
are on their own, and again at the customary mid-sixties retirement age. After
about age seventy, migration rates tend to rise a little, presumably reflecting
adjustments to death of the spouse or to growing incapacity.
These
characteristic life-cycle variations are manifest in Figure 10-1, showing United States migration rates by
age and sex. The pattern is blurred in the aggregate, of course, by the fact
that not all people enter the labor force, marry, or retire at the same ages.
But age remains the characteristic most distinctly associated with
migration-rate differentials. Most of the migration that occurs (except in
massive displacements of populations by military or political force or by
natural disaster) is done by people in young adult age groups.
Certain
other individual characteristics also substantially affect migration rates. The
most important are marital status, parenthood, and level of education. Table
10-5 shows migration rates over a five-year interval for men in three mature
age groups (that is, after their schooling was probably completed), according
to amount of schooling. We see that higher education is associated with higher
migration rates. Occupational status also has a bearing on migration rates. For
a given age category, individuals with higher occupational status have greater
mobility.19
In addition
to such regularly recorded characteristics as we have considered, individuals
have many other personal characteristics that influence their propensity to
migrate. Some people are simply more footloose, more adventurous, more easily
dissatisfied, or more ambitious than others, or in countless other ways more
mobile.
These wide
differences in migration rates among different kinds of people mean, of course,
that those who migrate are almost never a representative cross section of the
population of either their area of origin or their area of destination. A
migration stream substantially alters the make-up of the population and the
labor force in both areas.
The selectivity of migration is greatest when the journey is difficult, when
the areas of origin and destination are in sharp contrast, and when the
population itself is highly diverse in such characteristics as education,
income level, occupational experience, and ethnic or racial background.
Migrants generally seem to be somewhat above the average of the origin area in terms of energy, ability, and training; this suggests that the
direct effect on the remaining population is to lower its average "quality."
One of the oldest clichés regarding emigration, in fact, is that it
tends to drain the best people out of an area, thus damaging the prospects for
industrialization or other economic development.
An
intensive study of the occupational status of American men aged twenty to
sixty-four came to these conclusions:
Migration has
become increasingly selective of high potential achievers in recent
decades.
The careers of migrants
are in almost all comparisons, clearly superior to those of nonmigrants. . . .
Whether migration between regions or between communities is examined; whether
migrants are compared to nonmigrants within ethnic-nativity groupings or
without employing these controls; whether education and first job are held
constant; and whether migrants are compared to natives in their place of origin
or their place of destination migrants tend to attain higher occupational
levels and to experience more upward mobility than nonmigrants, with Only a few
exceptions.
Migrants from urban
places, though not those from rural areas, enjoy higher status than the natives
in the community to which they have come, regardless of its size.20
These
findings go well beyond the traditional folklore about selective migration in
that they suggest (1) that migrants (except from rural areas) tend to be
superior to the population of the destination area as well as of the
origin area, and (2) that selectivity may be increasing, contrary to the
expectation that more general literacy and other trends enhance the mobility of
an increasing proportion of the population.
Another
study, relating to migrants to the industrial metropolis of Monterrey, Mexico,
between 1940 and 196021 gives a rather different
picture. Migration appears to have become much less selective with respect to
populations of origin in that interval. Early in the period, only a few of the
more highly educated ventured the move to the city; later, mobility increased,
so that villagers of all educational and income levels became more nearly
representative of the populations of its areas of origin, while at the
same time it was becoming increasingly different from (educationally inferior
to) the population of the urban destination area.22
Migration
selectivity, then, can depend to a large extent on the state of development of
the regions involved and can change in character fairly rapidly. It has already
been suggested that a broadening of education and economic opportunity in
less-developed regions can reduce selectivity. Finally, Everett Lee has
proposed a plausible but not easily verifiable hypothesis: that migration
motivated by pull tends to be positively selective (i.e., the more
productive people are the ones who go), whereas migration motivated by push
tends to be negatively selective.
Factors at origin
operate most stringently against persons who in some way have failed
economically or socially. Though there are conditions in many places which push
out the unorthodox and the highly creative, it is more likely to be the
uneducated or the disturbed who are forced to migrate.23
Inward, Outward, and Net Migration: Three Hypotheses. The typical age selectivity of migration is sometimes an important factor
accounting for the observed tendency that places with high in-migration rates
have high out-migration rates as well. The most mobile age groups (and perhaps
also the individuals most mobile by temperament or other characteristics) are
present in abnormally high proportion in a fast-growing area with high recent
and current in-migration; and such local demographic characteristics play a
large part in determining how many people leave an area.24
We have
learned that the relationships among inward, outward, and net migration are
more complex than one might suspect. Let us review them in terms of three
hypotheses or "laws of migration," using Figure 10-2 as a graphic aid.
The naive
or common-sense" expectation regarding migration into and out of an area is
that if the area is attractive as a place to work and live, there will be a net
inward flow reflecting large inward and small outward migration; while if the
area is unattractive, there will be a net outflow reflecting large outward and
small inward migration. This hypothesis is represented diagrammatically in the
first panel, (a), of Figure 10-2, where the
dots could represent different labor market areas or the same area at different
times. In-migration and out-migration rates are measured on the horizontal and
vertical axes respectively. The 45-degree line represents zero net migration.
The various areas show a pattern of negative correlation of out-migration, with
both inward and net migration: "Attractive" areas are those in the lower right
part of the scatter, and "unattractive" areas are those above and to the left
of the diagonal.
The second
panel, (b), depicts the contrasting relationship, previously suggested
on the basis of migration selectivity and other factors, which we might
designate as the Lowry hypothesis. Here the rate of out-migration is positively correlated with both inward and net migration.
Still
another view is that shown in the third panel, (c), which we may call
the Beale hypothesis.25 Using 1955-1960 data for
509 State Economic Areas demarcated by the Census Bureau,26Beale discovered a relationship schematically
resembling that of Figure 10-2 (c). He found
that high gross out-migration can be associated with either high net
in-migration or high net out-migration. The net rate is mainly determined by
out-migration when the net is negative, and by in-migration when the net is
positive. We may interpret this as meaning that the "Lowry effect" dominates in
relatively prosperous and growing areas; whereas in areas that are seriously
depressed the predominant effect is the "common-sense" one: Poor prospects both
discourage inflow and encourage outflow, and economic factors exert both pull
and push.
The
significance of this issue is far from trivial, as Beale points out and as we
shall more fully appreciate in the context of Chapters 11 and 12. If migration out of seriously depressed or
backward areas is assumed to be affected only by demographic characteristics of
the population and not by the level of unemployment or income, then measures to
stimulate activity in such areas would not reduce out-migration (in fact,
according to the Lowry hypothesis they would eventually increase it). The Beale
findings suggest, however, that such stimulus may, in some cases at least,
retard out-migration. In choosing among policy decisions regarding aid to
depressed or backward areas, it is of some importance to try to gauge this
possible impact.
Changes in Migration Rates. There are a number of
reasons why one might expect migration rates to increase over time. Lee has
suggested that increasing diversity of the opportunities afforded by different
areas, increasingly diverse specialization of peoples capabilities and
preferences, the beaten-path effect, and the increasingly wide knowledge and
experience of other locations that is brought about by education, better
communication, more income, and increased leisure to travel would each enhance
the mobility of the population.
Changes in
the socioeconomic and demographic characteristics of households have been
working in the opposite direction, however. For short-distance (intracounty)
moves, decreases in average size of household and increases in home ownership
are associated with decreases in mobility. With respect to long-distance moves,
the rising incidence of two-wage-earner households also discourages
mobility.
Recent
tabulations of migration data gathered on an annual basis from sample surveys
since 1948 show that the net effect of these countervailing forces has been a
consistent decline in the overall migration rate. For example, the average
annual rate for the twelve-month period March to March has fallen from 20.6 in
1961-1962 to 18.7 in 1970-1971 and to 17.2 in 1980-1981. Thus in the 1960-1961
period, roughly 21 percent of the population changed residences in the United
States, whereas that number had fallen to about 17 percent in the 1980-1981
period.27
Much of
this trend can be attributed to decreases in the frequency of intracounty
moves. However, there are also indications that regions have become more alike,
so that in some respects the incentives for long-distance moves have
probably lessened. Regional incomes in any case have tended to converge toward
the national average. Thus in addition to the socioeconomic and demographic
factors mentioned above, reduced migration incentives could also have offset
increases in personal mobility.
Migration
rates show marked seasonal and cyclical variations. In general, prosperity
favors migration because opportunities are more plentiful, risks of
unemployment at the new location are less, and migrants themselves are in a
better financial position. In periods of economic recession or depression,
people tend to look for the place with the best economic security. This may
mean staying where they are or (in the case of fairly recent migrants)
returning to their last place of residence. Thus the long-term migration stream
toward places with better long-term prospects is temporarily interrupted or
even reversed by severe recessions. For example, in the worst years of the
Great Depression of the 1930s, the longstanding net flows of migrants from farm
to nonfarm areas and from foreign countries to the United States were both
temporarily reversed.
The Effectiveness of
Migration. When people migrate, they are seeking to better their
prospects. How well does migration accomplish that purpose, and how does it
affect people other than those who migrate?
The answer obviously
depends in part on how accurately people size up the prospects when they decide
to move (or not to). The better informed they are, the greater the probability
that migration will justify itself and will contribute to a more efficient
allocation of human resources in the economy as a whole. Thus public policy
with regard to migration should, first, help potential migrants to get the
information they need for rational choice. Beyond this rather obvious point,
the question of the effectiveness of migration can be examined on three
different levels.
- The "efficiency of
migration" between any two areas is sometimes defined as the ratio of the net
flow to the total gross flow in both directions. In other words, if all
migrants go in the same direction, the efficiency is 100 percent, in the sense
that there is no cross-hauling of migrants: The net flow equals the gross flow.
At the other extreme, if the flows in the two directions just balance, so that
there is no net movement at all, the efficiency is said to be zero.
This measure may be useful in suggesting the degree to which a net migration
figure can be misleading as an indicator of the amount of movement; but it has
little to do with efficiency in any meaningful sense. People are not simply
interchangeable units of manpower, as the efficiency ratio implies. On the
contrary, those moving in one direction may be presumed to differ qualitatively
from those moving in the other; with each stream believing, and perhaps
correctly, that it is going in the right direction. Accordingly, a situation in
which two opposing flows largely cancel out in terms of numbers of people is
not necessarily indicative of any "lost motion" or waste in terms of either the
welfare of the individual migrants or the socially desirable spatial allocation
of manpower resources.
- A different and somewhat
more sophisticated question about migration is to ask whether it seems to be
going to the right places so far as the economic benefit to the migrant is
concerned. If we find people moving predominantly from places of lower incomes
to places of higher incomes, or from areas of heavy unemployment to labor
shortage areas, we surmise that they know what they are doing. If they go the
other way, or simply in all directions without any apparent regard to income or
employment differentials or any other obvious index of advantage, we have to
surmise either that the migrants are ignorant about the alternatives or that we
are ignorant about their real motivations.
Actually, most migration
flows do fit a "rational" pattern in relation to observable differences in
earning levels, unemployment rates, and such other easily identified variables
as climate and the level of public assistance benefits. Even the migration of
poor blacks from Southern farms to Northern city ghettos with high unemployment
and dismal living conditions can make sense in terms of improvement in the
migrants incomes, at any rate if we ignore possible adverse effects on
the social adjustment of the individuals and communities involved.
In
relating migration to indices of community economic welfare (for example, wage
or income levels) we cannot reasonably assume that the migrant immediately fits
into the pattern of the area and receives the average pay, employment security,
and other perquisites of the residents in his or her age and occupational
category. Migrants are no more representative of the populations of their
destination areas than they are of the populations of their areas of origin.
Some of their distinctive characteristics are subject to modification, so that
if they stay they will tend to become more similar to their new neighbors. This
tendency toward assimilation applies to skills, consumption patterns, ratings
on most kinds of "intelligence" tests, desired number of children, and social
behavior.
- Finally, we can judge
migration on the basis of how much it contributes to aggregate output or, more
broadly, to general social welfare. This is the appropriate level of judgment
for public authorities and public-spirited citizens to try to use. It calls for
assessing the effects of migration not just on the migrants but on the
communities they leave and enter.
This is by no means a simple
criterion to apply. On the face of it, the transfer of manpower to places where
its productivity is higher seems likely to raise national per capita output and
increase "aggregate welfare," insofar as that term has any meaning. And
differentials in real-earnings rates reflect, roughly at least, differentials
in the marginal productivity of labor. But migration (particularly highly
selective migration) can have important side effects (externalities) on the
areas involved, in terms of the costs of public services, the prospects for
future economic development, and the quality of life. The discussion of these
problems will be taken up in later chapters where we come to grips with the
processes of regional growth and change.
10.4 LABOR ORIENTATION: THE DEMAND FOR LABOR AT A
LOCATION
Our
discussion of mobility and migration has shed some light on what determines the
supply of labor at different places. To the extent that people move to places
offering more jobs or higher earnings, the labor supply adjusts to the spatial
pattern of labor demand. In areas where demand has grown relative to supply and
there are hindrances to inward migration, a tight labor market is manifest by
low unemployment rates and relatively high earnings; in places where labor
demand has declined or has failed to keep pace with the growth in the labor
force (resulting in part from natural increase of the population) and outward
migration is not easy, we find a labor surplus manifest in high unemployment
rates and relatively low earnings rates. This is, of course, a somewhat
simplified picture; many areas, at any given time, do not fit wholly into
either of these two contrasting categories.
On the
demand side, we envisage employers of labor as being concerned about its costs
and seeking to make profitable adjustments to such labor cost differentials as
they are aware of.
What, then,
will employers do if labor is expensive (relative to its productivity) in a
specific location? They have three possible ways of economizing on this
expensive labor: changing their production techniques so as to substitute other
inputs (for example, labor-saving machinery) for manpower; going out of
business; or moving to a different location where labor is cheaper. Where the
last two choices are seriously considered, we can say that the activity in
question is locationally sensitive to labor supply, or to some degree is labor-oriented.
The degree
of labor orientation varies widely among activities. In one extreme case
(activities tightly tied to a locality by market orientation, orientation to
inputs other than labor, or some other compulsion), labor costs may have no
significant locational effect at allthe employers demand for labor
at that location is highly inelastic. Retail trade and local services
illustrate this category of locally bound industries essentially unaffected by
labor cost differentials. If, for example, drugstore clerks were paid twice as
much in Milwaukee as in Akron, this would not induce Milwaukee drugstore
proprietors to relocate to Akron. Their market is entirely local. They are not
in competition with Akron in any sense and only need to assure themselves that
they are not paying their clerks more bounteously than their Milwaukee
competitors. There would, however, be a stronger incentive in Milwaukee than in
Akron to skimp on labor and substitute other inputs if possible. In the case
assumed, we might expect Milwaukee drugstores to be quicker to install such
things as vending machines, change-making cash registers, and display layouts
facilitating self-service.
At the
other extreme, we have strongly labor-oriented activities, those whose
demand for labor at any particular location is highly elasticunless labor
is cheap, they will close down or go elsewhere. Normally, these are activities
that are rather footloose with respect to location factors other than labor
supply. A change of location makes relatively little difference in their costs
of transfer, level of sales, or outlays for other local inputs per unit of
sales, while their labor costs do vary markedly from one location or region to
another. Historically, the manufacture of textiles and standard clothing has
been strongly oriented to low-wage labor, while labor-intensive activities
requiring scarce special skills have been strongly oriented to the few places
where such skills are available.
Until
rather recently, most activities oriented to cheap labor as such mainly
employed unskilled or semiskilled blue-collar workers; but nowadays there are
numerous instances of firms moving to places where there is cheap white-collar
clerical labor. This is partly the result of the rapidly increasing proportion
of white-collar to total employment; but the locational effect also reflects
the increased availability of qualified clerical help in small
communities.
10.5 THE RATIONALE OF LABOR COST DIFFERENTIALS
Having
briefly considered the location of manpower from both the supply side and the
demand side, we now have some insight into the rather complex set of
interrelations shown schematically in Figure 10-3.
This diagram may be useful in reminding us of the interdependencies and tracing
the repercussions of different kinds of change. For example, the mechanism
implied by the concept of equalizing differentials in wages (that is, the
tendency of migration to eliminate real-income differentials) involves the
simple feedback sequence of effects shown by the solid lines in the
diagram below.
A more
complex and realistic model of the equalization process, taking into account
the fact that the price of labor affects living costs through the price of
locally produced goods and services, would include in addition the effects
shown by dashed lines in the same diagram. In either model, the
equalization effect is finished when there are no longer any real-income
differentials (that is, equilibrium has been reached, as far as the employee is
concerned). The reader may find it useful to trace out in a similar fashion,
using Figure 10-3 as a guide, what happens as
labor-oriented employers shift their hiring to areas of low labor
cost.
10.5.1
Where Are Labor Costs Low?
What are
the types of location to which a labor-oriented activity is attracted? There is
no single, simple answer to this question, mainly because different activities
and individual firms are seeking different kinds of labor cost economy. In some
jobs, one worker can perform as well as another. For such a job, labor is a
rather homogeneous input, and the wage rate is a good measure of labor cost. In
other occupations, skills and aptitudes vary widely, and a poor worker is not a
bargain at any wage. In some activities, the nature of the product, the type of
work, and the volume of output are highly changeable, and the employer wants to
be able to arrange with a minimum of difficulty for changes in job
specifications, short layoffs, overtime, and other changes. In such an
activity, good labor supply locations may be those where the local pool of
labor is large, where the average age and seniority of workers is low, or where
union bargaining has not built up a rigid structure of work rules.
Each
activity, then, will have its own preferences among labor supply locations,
determined by the relative emphasis it puts on low wages, skill or
trainability, and flexibility.
Low wages
are most often found in relatively backward areas where the demand for labor
has not kept up with the natural increase of the labor force. Obviously, these
are areas where manpower is impounded, as it were, by its imperfect outward
mobility. Less obviously, such areas tend to develop certain characteristics
that impede out-migration.
Many such
areas specialize heavily in kinds of employment for which the demand has grown
slowly or declined (for example, general farming or coal mining). This may, in
fact, be the chief reason why they are areas of labor surplus. But this
specialization also means that their labor force lacks experience in more
dynamic industries or occupations, which is a disadvantage in seeking work
elsewhere. There are attitudinal barriers, too, to giving up an occupation in
which one has acquired skill and seniority in order to start near the bottom in
a new trade. Derelict coal-mining villages in Appalachia are full of
middle-aged and older ex-miners who are slow to consider any alternative line
of work, even though it may be clear that the local mine is closed for good.
Finally, the very existence of a labor surplus and low wages helps to lower the
cost of such major budget items as shelter and services, and this helps to
diminish the economic incentive to move out.
The
advantages of experience and skill in a labor supply are most often found in
areas where the educational level is high and where activities requiring some
special skills have been concentrated for a long time. The supply of some types
of highly paid and scarce manpower (such as scientific and other specialists,
or persons of high artistic capability) is coming to be located increasingly in
areas and communities of high physical and cultural amenity, since those types
of people are in such demand that they can afford to be quite choosy about
where they are willing to live. It is no accident or whim that has located so
many advanced-technology and research-oriented activities in pleasant places
near major universities.
Flexibility
and diversity of labor supply are most likely to be found in a large labor
market in an intensively urbanized region, although one might surmise that the
rapid population growth of nonmetropolitan areas during the 1970s has increased
the diversity of labor supply in many less developed places as well. In some
large urban labor markets, however, the potential labor economies of size and
diversity are partly offset by the greater rigidity of union work rules and
bargaining practices, and the greater age and seniority of the work force that
characterize an area where an activity has developed a mature
concentration.
The
different kinds of labor cost advantage (low wage rates, skill, and flexibility
and diversity of supply) are unlikely to be found in the same places, because
to some extent they reflect contrasting area characteristics. Thus low wage
rates are associated with less developed areas having low living costs.
Experience and diversity of supply are often associated with the opposite type
of location: large urban areas in advanced industrialized regions having
relatively high living costs. Any given area, then, tends to be classified
according to the aspect of labor supply in which it has the greatest
comparative advantage.
10.5.2
Indirect Advantages of Labor Quality
The cost
savings involved in the use of highly productive (that is, skilled and/or
adaptable) manpower are sometimes underestimated, because not all of them show
up in labor cost per se. Recall the case of Harkinsville and Parkston discussed
in Chapter 2. Harkinsville workers work
faster, and get correspondingly higher hourly wages, than those in Parkston.
Thus there is no difference in labor cost per hour. Nevertheless, it will be
recalled, Harkinsville is a better location for the employer. For example, if
the output of the firm is to be 1000 units a day at whichever location is
chosen, the production worker payroll will be the same at either location; but
the plant can be smaller at Harkinsville. This means a smaller investment in
land and buildings; a smaller parking lot and cafeteria; fewer washrooms,
drinking fountains, and other facilities; a smaller work load for payroll
accounting and personnel management; and so on. Only such cost items as are
geared directly to the volume of output and not the number of people working
will be as large in Harkinsville as in Parkston: for example, production
materials, shipping containers, motive power and fuel for processing, and
loading and handling facilities.
10.5.3
Institutional Constraints on Wages and Labor Costs
To an
increasing extent in most countries, the supply of labor to an individual
employer at one location is affected by bargaining procedures and constraints
involving other employers and other locations as well. In activities where the
employing firms are few and large and where a strong labor organization
includes a major fraction of the workers, key negotiations can set a
quasi-national pattern of fringe benefits and work rules subject to only minor
local differences. Examples include the steel and automobile industries and
rail and air transportation. In still other activities, agreements cover major
sections of the activity (such as the East Coast ports with respect to handling
ship cargo).
Multiarea
bargaining introduces a strong additional equalization element into the wage
pattern. Even more generally, labor organizations with aspirations for
nationwide power try to work toward elimination of regional wage differentials.
Lower wages in areas of weaker organization are viewed as a threat to
employment in the areas of stronger organization and higher wages, since
employers are naturally tempted to move to save labor costs. And employers not
contemplating such a move are, of course, in favor of higher labor costs for
their competitors. Both parties, then, may well favor extension of the
geographical area of wage bargaining and the enactment of federal and state
minimum-wage laws, which limit differentials still further.
There are
often pressures toward similarity of pay rates and fringe benefit levels among
different activities and occupations within a single-labor market. This means
that if there are important high-wage activities in an area, they tend to some
extent to set the tone for related types of employment in the same area and to
make it generally a higher-cost area than it might otherwise be.
It is easy
to see how this works between occupations calling for similar qualifications,
so that the various activities in the community are competing in a common pool
of available workers with those qualifications. For example, steel workers are
relatively highly paid; as a result, a community dominated by steel making is
likely to have relatively high wage scales in construction and in other kinds
of employment not too different in their requirements from the jobs of many
steel mill employees. There would be no such direct effect, however, on wage
rates for sales or clerical workers.
Furthermore, unions of the dominant industry in a community generally
organize a number of other industries as well, the jurisdictional lines being
rather loose. Thus in Pittsburgh, metal fabricating plants are mainly organized
by the steelworkers union, while similar plants in Detroit have locals of
the automobile workers union. Though such a union does not necessarily
find it feasible or desirable to extend the wage and benefits pattern in the
dominant industry to the other industries it has organized in the same
community, there is certainly some pressure in that direction, and a consequent
reinforcing of the tendency toward intraarea wage level conformity.28
This
tendency is not area-wide, as a rule. For example, in the Pittsburgh labor
market area the upward wage pressures arising from the importance of some
tightly organized and high-paying industries are essentially restricted to
blue-collar occupations traditionally dominated by male workers, which heavily
predominate in the major industries involved. For many years, however,
Pittsburgh wages in retail trade and generally for jobs traditionally held by
women tended to be a little lower than those in cities of comparable size in
the same part of the country. Presumably, this reflected the relatively slow
growth of the area as a whole and the relative surplus of employable women
arising from the predominance of male jobs in the area. It is interesting to
note that in the late 1950s the differentials began to disappear, perhaps
reflecting vigorous local growth in office employment and no growth in heavy
industry employment.29
It has been
observed that the wage spread or skill margin among different occupations
within a single labor market is generally wider in less developed and slower
growing regions. This has been explained in terms of the lower educational
standards and the smaller proportion of semiskilled manufacturing jobs in such
areas, since education and the availability of an accessible "ladder" of skill
development both enhance occupational mobility and make the labor market more
competitive.30
A further
explanation lies in the tendency for people of higher occupational,
educational, and earnings levels to be geographically more mobile. As a result,
regional differentials in their earnings are narrower than is the case for
lower-status people.31In an area of labor surplus
and out-migration, it is the people in the better-paid occupations who move out
most readily; a relatively larger differential is required to move the
unskilled. The wage spread in such a labor market is consequently wide compared
to that in a more prosperous and active place.
10.5.4 Complementary
Labor
Different
categories of labor are to some extent jointly supplied; that is, the supply of
one kind of labor in an area depends on how much of the other kind is there. A
local population or potential labor force is almost always an assortment of
people of different ages, sexes, and physical and mental capabilities. If most
of the jobs available in the area call for superior aptitude, the area is
likely to have a surplus of people with more pedestrian abilities, and these
may represent a bargain in labor supply for an activity with less exacting
requirements. Conversely, if all the jobs in an area involve rugged manual
labor, there is likely to be a surplus of not quite so rugged individuals, who
might represent a bargain labor supply for an activity not requiring physical
strength.
We have to
consider, then, as another kind of advantageous labor location for an activity,
places where there is a heavy demand for some kind of contrasting and
complementary labor. This principle assumes, of course, that mobility is quite
imperfect, so that not all the different types of workers are able to seek out
the locations where their own kind of work is best rewarded.
The most
important basis for such restriction is inherent in family ties. In a
familys choice of location from the standpoint of income, the most
important consideration is opportunity and earnings for the principal earner,
usually the head of the family. The spouse, and any other full or partial
dependents of working age, is then part of the potential labor supply in the
area where the principal wage earner locates. Accordingly, a labor market
heavily specialized in activities employing men is likely to have a plentiful
and relatively cheap female labor supply, and a labor market heavily
specialized in activities employing mature adults is likely to have a plentiful
and relatively cheap supply of young labor of both sexes.
Historically, many industries have owed their start in certain areas
to a complementary labor supply generated in such a way. A classic case is the
making of shoes in colonial days in eastern Massachusetts. The coastal area
north of Boston was heavily specialized in the male occupations of sailing and
fishing; this created a large complementary labor surplus of wives and
daughters, who were able to supplement family incomes by making
shoesfirst at home and later in small factories.32 At a later period, the anthracite mining area of eastern Pennsylvania
attracted a substantial amount of the silk-weaving industry on a similar basis.
As late as the 1920s, it was observed that in the anthracite area about 60
percent of the silk weavers were women, while in the previous center of that
industry (in and around Paterson, New Jersey) 60 percent were men. The
manufacture of cheap standard garments, cigars, and light electrical equipment
and components also has historically been attracted to places offering
plentiful and cheap complementary labor.33
10.6 LABOR COST DIFFERENTIALS AND EMPLOYER LOCATIONS WITHIN AN
URBAN LABOR MARKET AREA
Up to this
point, we have been looking at the location of people and differentials in
earnings and labor costs on a macrogeographic scale, comparing labor markets as
units. A quite different set of considerations comes to the fore when we adopt
a microgeographic focus. Since the question of peoples residential
location preferences within urban areas has been dealt with in some detail in Chapters 6 and 7, we shall focus on the locational preferences
of employers as influenced by labor supply.
Although
labor market areas are in principle defined in terms of a feasible commuting
range, people prefer short work journeys to long ones, and as shown in Chapter 6, residential location decisions reflect
this and other access considerations. Thus the supply of labor to an employer
is not really ubiquitous throughout an urban area. Differential advantages of
labor supply within a local labor market are particularly significant when the
employer wants a special type of labor or a large supply of job candidates, and
in large labor market areas where residential areas are sharply differentiated
in character.
Thus if an
activity mainly employs a class of people dependent on public transportation to
get to work (for example, very low-income people or married people whose
spouses preempt the family car for their own commuting), it may have difficulty
in recruiting an adequate work force in the less accessible suburban areas.
Even if there is not an absolute shortage of applicants, there may not be
enough of a surplus of applicants to allow much freedom of
selection.
In the late
1950s, a study was made of the recruiting experiences of business firms in the
Boston metropolitan area which had relocated to sites along a circumferential
suburban freeway.34Most of the establishments in
the sample canvassed were sizable manufacturing plants, with electronics
equipment the most numerous category. Every firm in the sample had made an
advance survey of the residential and commuting patterns of its employees in an
effort to anticipate any recruitment problems that the new location might
involve. Several of the firms took explicit account of employee residential
locations in choosing the specific section of the highway on which to relocate.
Every firm found it necessary to establish a plant cafeteria at the new
location.
The
surveys findings on recruitment problems were summed up as
follows:
A summary of the
observations of personnel managers interviewed indicated a general, but not
universal, conclusion that Route 128 locations in comparison with the downtown
areas definitely eased recruitment of engineering, professional and
administrative staff, but neither helped nor hindered recruitment of skilled
labor. Recruiting difficulties arose especially when the firms sought young,
female clerical workers, male unskilled workers, and seasonal workers, both
male and female, particularly in the higher income suburbs of the western
subarea of Route 128. The type of recruitment problem mentioned most frequently
was that of the younger, unmarried female, clerical workers.
The most
serious of the recruitment problems was that of unskilled production labor,
both male and female, but especially male, for seasonal work. Although this
problem did not arise frequently, the need for a seasonal expansion of
employment could cause a major headache for the personnel department, and
[seems?] to indicate very sharply the lack of a casual labor market in the
suburbs. At a downtown location, a firm could readily draw unskilled male and
female workers with a "Help Wanted" sign in the window for seasonal employment.
At a Route 128 location, this type of labor was scarce, and intown labor found
commuting to the plant time-consuming and costly for low-paying jobs on a
seasonal basis.
. . .The existence of a circumferential highway or of
a few long-distance commuters does not lead to the conclusion that there is
also a circumferential labor market, in which a firm at any one location can
draw equally well from any other part of the area. On the contrary it would
appear as if suburban firms tend to draw from areas nearby, and lose those
workers who live at abnormally long distances away.
. . .Relationship
of a firm to the immediate local labor supply seems to be crucial. Where the
local supply is already committed, or of the wrong composition to meet the
demands of the firm, the company will be forced to rely on longer-distance
commuters. If this means extension of commuting beyond the normal range, or
direction, for that type of labor, the firm will be likely to have major labor
supply difficulties)35
It has been more than a
quarter of a century since this report was published, but these findings are
still relevant. The area around Route 128 (now an interstate highway) has
become one of the nations major centers for advanced-technology
activities; and as the metropolitan area has grown, the labor market in the
vicinity of this highway has diversified substantially. However, the
recruitment problems described in the reports summary are now
characteristic of firms considering locations on a yet more remote beltway
I-495 around the Boston metropolitan area.
More recent
and more elaborate studies have brought out some additional details concerning
the characteristics of urban labor markets, For example, Albert Bees and George
Shultz found in the Chicago labor market significant wage differentials for the
same occupation among different neighborhoods within the metropolitan area,
corresponding generally to the directions of commuter flow.36Similar differentials have also been identified on the
basis of distance from the central business district.37 The labor market of a large metropolis is clearly not a
single spatially perfect market in the sense that location within it makes no
difference.
As one
might expect, the least mobile types of manpower (low-skilled workers, members
of minority groups whose housing location choice is restricted by
discrimination, and secondary and complementary workers)38evince the greatest market imperfection in terms of
differentials in their net earnings after deducting commuting costs. This same
tendency toward wider geographical wage differentials for lower-income
occupational groups has already been noted at the interregional
level.
Workers are
attracted in their residential choices toward job locations, whereas employers
are attracted toward cheap labor supply. The relative force of these two sides
of a mutual linkage varies widely among occupations, of course. At one extreme,
the wage rate in an occupation is uniform throughout the labor market area, and
the commuters from more distant residential areas bear all of the extra money
and time costs of commuting over those greater distances. In the other extreme
case, the employers pay higher wages at job locations farther from employee
residential areas, absorbing the added costs of commuting longer distances by
paying compensating differentials in wages.39
The amount
of variation in wages in any given occupation will depend on the relative
mobility of the employees and the employers and also on the extent to which
union agreements or understandings among employers impose a single wage
standard for the whole labor market area. It will depend also on two factors
already mentioned; namely, the skill and income level of the occupation itself
and the extent to which the workers residential choices are limited by
discrimination.
It is clear
that the spatial imperfection of large urban labor markets affects particularly
the low-income worker. One of the most serious aspects of the present-day
problem of inadequate job opportunities for residents of urban slums is that an
increasing proportion of the kinds of jobs they might fill has shifted to
distant suburban locations with little or no public transportation available,
while very few employers have been willing to accept some obvious disadvantages
of a slum location for the sake of closer access to that labor
supply.
10.7 SUMMARY
Several
kinds of spatial differentials in earnings and income are of interest to
various parties. The relative opulence of two communities can be compared in a
marketing survey in terms of total or per capita money income. An individual
looking for a good place to work would be interested in wage rates or annual
earnings in his or her specific occupation, adjusted for any differences in the
cost of living. An employer looking for low labor costs would want to compare
specific wage scales, adjusted for productivity and fringe benefits.
Relative
pay levels in specific occupations in the United States show a pattern of
interregional differentials, with lower levels in the South and in smaller
labor markets. These two differentials (North-South, and size of place) appear
also in measures of per capita annual income and living costs. Income and pay
levels deflated by cost-of-living indices seem also to show similar patterns,
but to a much smaller degree. The term "equalizing differentials" is applied to
a differential in money wages or income that merely compensates for a
cost-of-living differential.
People move
in response to perceived differences in prospective real incomes as well as
other factors; migration flows depend on the characteristics of both the origin
and the destination areas, the difficulties of the journey, and the
characteristics of the migrant. Within a labor market area, housing and
personal considerations account for most moves; for migration between labor
market areas, job-related reasons are the most important.
The cost
and difficulty of migration is roughly related to distance, and migration
streams do show attenuation with distance, which can be expressed in a
gravity-type migration model. Social distance is a broader term designed
to take account of the degree of sociocultural adjustment required of the
migrant in addition to costs of distance per se. Such considerations account
for the beaten-path effect (migration is easier along paths used by many
previous migrants from the same area).
Age is the
personal characteristic most markedly related to migration rates, with
generally declining rates to the late teens, a sharp peak around age eighteen
to twenty, and a decelerating decline to old age with a small peak at
retirement time. Migration rates are positively associated with both education
and occupational status or skill, at any given ages.
Places with
high rates of in-migration tend to have high rates of outward migration as
well, because of the beaten-path effect and also because heavy in-migration
produces a population with characteristics conducive to high mobility in terms
of age, education, family status, disposition, and migration experience.
Earnings levels and employment opportunity affect the amount of in-migration to
a labor market but seem to have little effect on out-migration rates except in
seriously distressed areas.
There has
been a decline in overall migration rates in the United States since World War
II. The factors contributing to this decline differ for short- and
long-distance moves, but they include decreases in the average size of
households, increased home ownership, and greater incidence of two-wage-earner
households. Regions have also become more alike, thus reducing the incentive to
migrate.
Labor
mobility and the lack of it play a part in the development of labor cost
differentials, which in turn affect the location of some interregionally
footloose activities. Each such activity has its own preferences among labor
supply locations, determined by the relative emphasis it places upon low wages,
skill or trainability, and flexibility.
Low wages
are most often found in relatively backward and/or depressed areas where labor
demand has not kept up with the natural increase of the labor force.
Limitations on outward mobility, particularly for the poor and less skilled,
dam up in such places a pool of cheap surplus labor. In addition, low-cost
complementary or secondary labor supplies occur in areas where there is a
relatively heavy demand for the kind of labor services provided by the
principal earners of families but relatively little demand for the services of
other family members such as spouses or children.
For
activities requiring a highly skilled or educated labor force, developed areas
with high amenity are more likely to furnish the desired kind of labor supply.
Flexibility and diversity of labor supply are most likely to be found in large
metropolitan areas; however, these advantages are partially offset by more
restrictive work and seniority rules.
Institutional constraints and the wage-bargaining procedures
associated with large employee and employer organizations generally work in the
direction of greater interregional wage uniformity in a given industry or
occupation and also greater local uniformity among different industries and
occupations within a single labor market area. There is some tendency for the
wage spread between occupations to be wider in areas of slow employment growth
or decline, reflecting in large part the higher mobility of the better-paid
occupations.
Within
large labor market areas, distance and commuting costs produce significant
differentials in available labor supply, which are reflected in partially
compensatory wage premiums at locations relatively far from workers
residential areas.
TECHNICAL TERMS INTRODUCED IN THIS CHAPTER |
Spatial
mobility |
Chain
migration |
Equalizing
differentials in wages and incomes |
Migration
rate |
Real differentials in
wages and incomes |
Selectivity of
migration |
Pull and push factors
motivating migration |
Positively and
negatively selective migration |
Social
distance |
Lowry
hypothesis |
Functional
distance |
Beale
hypothesis |
Beaten-path
effect |
Labor-oriented
activities |
Counterstream
effect |
Compensating wage
differentials |
SELECTED
READINGS
Michael J.
Geenwood, "Research on Internal Migration in the United States: A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature, 13, 2 (June 1975), 397-433.
Irving
Hoch, "Income and City Size," Urban Studies, 9, 3 (October 1972),
229-328.
Chang-I Hua
and Frank Porell, "A Critical Review of the Development of the Gravity Model," International Regional Science Review, 4, 2 (Winter 1979),
97-125.
Albert Rees
and George P. Shultz, Workers and Wages in an Urban Labor Market (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1970).
Harry W.
Richardson, Regional Economics (Urbana: University of Illinois Press,
1978), Chapter 5.
Larry A.
Sjaastad, "The Costs and Returns of Human Migration," Journal of Political
Economy, 70, 5 (2) (Supplement, October 1962), 80-93.
ENDNOTES
1. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Handbook
of Labor Statistics, Bulletin 2070 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing
Office, 1980), Table 120, pp. 292-293.
2. C. T. Haworth and C. W. Rasmussen, "Determinants of Metropolitan
Cost of Living Variations," Southern Economic Journal, 40, 2 (October
1973), 183-192. See also Richard J. Cebula, "A Note on the Impact of
Right-to-Work Laws on the Cost of Living in the United States," Urban
Studies, 19, 2 (May 1982), 193-195.
3. The source for indices of consumer budget costs in selected
metropolitan areas is given in Table 10-4. Data on
per capita income for these and other metropolitan areas in 1980 can be found
in U.S. Department of Commerce, Regional Economic Measurement Division,
"Revised County and Metropolitan Area Personal Income," Survey of Current
Business, 64, 4 (April 1982), Table 1, pp. 51-52.
4. The most widely cited study documenting the positive correlation
of real income and population size in urban areas of the United States is
Irving Hoch, "Income and City Size," Urban Studies, 9, 3 (October 1972),
299-328. A much earlier study of workers hourly earnings and living costs
in Swedish industrial towns and cities showed a consistently positive
relationship, with roughly twice as wide a range of variation in earnings as in
living costs. The same study found consistently higher living costs in larger
communities and in regions more distant from food-producing areas or having
especially rigorous climates. See Bertil Ohlin, Interregional and
International Trade (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1933), pp.
215-218.
5. See Steven H. Sandell, "Women and the Economics of Family
Migration," Review of Economics and Statistics, 59, 4 (November 1977),
406-414; and Jacob Mincer, "Family Migration Decisions," Journal of
Political Economy, 86, 5 (October 1978), 749-773.
6. Of course, earnings and other benefits expected in the future must
be properly discounted if valid comparisons are to be made. The seminal article
recognizing this and other aspects of the individuals decision to migrate
as placing it among a number of human capital decisions, such as that to
"invest" in education or on-the-job training, is Larry A. Sjaastad, "The Costs
and Returns of Human Migration," Journal of Political Economy, 70, 5 (2)
(Supplement, October 1962), 80-93. This view has since come to dominate
empirical and theoretical attempts to explain migration on the basis of
economic incentives. For an excellent survey of these and related
developmentsat least until 1975see Michael J. Greenwood, "Research
on Internal Migration in the United States: A Survey," Journal of Economic
Literature, 13, 2 (June 1975), 397-433.
7. A number of recent studies have focused on quality-of-life factors
or looked at the relationship between quality-of-life and economic factors in
migration decisions. See, for example, Philip E. Graves, "Migration and
Climate," Journal of Regional Science, 20, 2 (May 1980), 227-238; and
Frank W. Porell, "Intermetropolitan Migration and the Quality of Life," Journal of Regional Science, 22, 2 (May 1982), 137-157.
8. Ohlin, Interregional Trade, p. 212. The term "equalizing"
has sometimes been applied also to wage differences explainable by differences
in the attractiveness of different occupations.
9. Separation of the push from the pull effect is obviously a tricky
business, and there has been much controversy about how much weight to attach
to each with respect to specific historical or current migrations. It has been
argued that the migrations from European countries to the United States in the
latter part of the nineteenth century were primarily motivated by pull, because
they fluctuated from year to year in harmony with fluctuations in American
business conditions but did not significantly vary in response to business
cycles in specific European countries. See Richard A. Easterlin, "Long Swings
in United States Demographic and Economic Growth: Some Findings on the
Historical Pattern," Demography, 2 (1965), 497-500.
10. See Ira S. Lowry, Migration and Metropolitan
Growth. Two Analytical Models (San Francisco: Chandler, 1966).
11. See Chang-I Hua and Frank Porell, "A Critical Review
of the Development of the Gravity Model," International Regional Science
Review, 4, 2 (Winter 1979), 97-125.
12. For a discussion of some issues relevant to the
interpretation of the distance factor, see Aba Schwartz, "Interpreting the
Effect of Distance on Migration," Journal of Political Economy, 81,5
(September/October 1973), 1153-1169.
13. H. ter Heide, "Migration Models and Their
Significance for Population Forecasts", Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, 41, 1 (January 1963), 63-64.
14. Functional distance is a still broader
concept, wrapping up in one index a measure of all factors impeding migration
between a given pair of points. Functional distance can be evaluated by
comparing actual migration flows with the flows that would he expected to occur
simply on the basis of, say, the populations of the points in question.
Functional distance can then be correlated with actual distance and other
suspected determinants in order to break it down into components.
15. See for example, James B. Kau and C. F. Sirmans,
"The Influence of Information Costs and Uncertainty on Migration: A Comparison
of Migrant Types," Journal of Regional Science, 17, 1 (April 1977),
89-96, where the role of previous migrants as a source of information is
examined statistically.
16. Lowell E. Galloway, Geographic Labor Mobility in
the United States, 1.957 to 1960, U.S. Department of Health, Education, and
Welfare, Social Security Administration, Office of Research and Statistics,
Research Report No. 28 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1969).
See also Janet R. Pack, "Determinants of Migration to Central Cities," Journal of Regional Science, 13, 2 (August 1973), 249-260.
17. E. G. Ravenstein, "The Laws of Migration," Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 52 (June 1889),
241-301.
18. Arthur
Redford, Labour Migration in England, 1800-1850 (Manchester: The
University Press, 1926; 2nd ed., New York: A. M. Kelley, 1968). The same
process was included as one of the basic principles of migration in
Ravensteins analysis. It may be surmised that chain migration is less
important than it once was in the United States, since the difficulties of
moving almost certainly depend less than they once did on the sheer physical
distance involved.
19. For example, see Table 28 beginning on page 60 of
the source cited in Table 10-5 for data on
metropolitan mobility by age and occupational group for the years 1975-1980).
Note however that these and almost all other such tabulations record
migrants characteristics as they were after the move. Many
migrants move in conjunction with a change of occupation, and to that extent
these figures are inaccurate in measuring migration probabilities of persons in
particular occupation groups.
20. Peter M. Blau and Otis Dudley Duncan, The
American Occupational Structure (New York: Wiley, 1967), pp.
271-272.
21. Harley L. Browning and Waltraut Feindt, "Selectivity
of Migrants to a Metropolis in a Developing Country: A Mexican Case Study," Demography, 6, 4 (November 1969), 347-357.
22. Where the quality (of education, skills, income, or
whatever) of a stream of migrants is, as in the Monterrey case, intermediate
between that of the origin and the destination populations, the curious result
is that the immediate effect of the migration is to lower the average quality
in both areas, although at the same time it usually improves the quality
of the migrants and of the populations of the areas combined! A similar
apparent paradox is involved in the case of the legendary student who flunked
out of Harvard and transferred to a rival New England institution (which shall
remain nameless), raising the average scholastic level of both
universities.
23 Everett S. Lee, "A Theory of Migration," Demography, 3, 1 (1966), 56. This article represents a thorough revision
and amplification of Ravensteins much earlier "Laws of
Migration.
24. See Lowry, Migration and Metropolitan
Growth.
25. Calvin L. Beale, "Demographic and Social
Considerations for U.S. Rural Economic Policy," American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, 51, 2 (May 1969), 410-427. A fuller account of
Beales findings appears in an unpublished paper, "The Relation of Gross
Outmigration Rates to Net Migration" (presented at the meetings of the
Population Association of America, Atlantic City, N. J., April
1969).
26. Lowrys study was restricted to major metropolitan labor market areas.
27. U. S. Bureau of the Census, Current Population
Reports, Series P-20, No. 377, Geographical Mobility: March 1980 to March
1981 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1983), Table A, p.
1.
28. On this and related questions, see Pittsburgh
Regional Planning Association, Region in Transition, Economic Study of
the Pittsburgh Region, vol. I (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press,
1963), Chapter 4, especially pp. 106-109.
29. Ibid.
30. See
Melvin W. Reder, "The Theory of Occupational Wage Differentials," American
Economic Review, 45, 5 (December 1955), 846-847.
31. This relationship was noted earlier in connection
with Table 10-1.
32. See E. M. Hoover, Location Theory and the Shoe
and Leather Industries (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1937),
pp. 109, 215-217, and sources cited therein.
33. Robert Murray Haig, "Toward an Understanding of the
Metropolis," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 40, 1 (February 1926),
195.
34. Everett J. Burtt, Jr., "Labor Supply Characteristics
of Route 128 Firms," Research Report No. 1-1958 (Boston: Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston, 1958; mimeographed).
35. The excerpts quoted here appear in a somewhat
altered sequence.
36. Albert Rees and George P. Shultz, Workers and
Wages in an Urban Labor Market (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1970).
37. See Randall W. Eberts and Timothy J. Gronberg, "Wage
Gradients, Rent Gradients, and the Price Elasticity of Demand for Housing: An
Empirical Investigation," Journal of Urban Economics, 12, 2 (September
1982), 168-176.
38. Secondary workers are those who are in the labor
force intermittently or part time. Complementary workers (see Section 10.5.4) are those who belong to a household in which
they are not the principal earner. There is of course a considerable overlap
between these categories.
39. Rees and Shultz found substantial evidence of
payment of part of the extra commuting costs of the more distant workers by
large establishments in the Chicago labor market in the late 1960s. (This does
not necessarily imply that specific employers paid wage premiums to those
individual workers who had the longer commuting journeys, but rather that
employers located long distances from residential areas of the type of workers
they employed tended to pay higher wages than did employers located closer to
such residential areas.) For a sample of workers in each of a number of
occupations, Rees and Shultz found a positive correlation between wage rate and
distance traveled to work when such other wage-influencing variables as the
age, seniority, education, and race of the worker were also included in the
regression equation. As a percentage of mean earnings, the extra compensation
for added travel time ranged from 2 percent for janitors to 13 ½ percent
for accountants. Rees and Shultz, Workers and Wages, pp. 169-175; see
also Hoch, "Income and City Size," p. 316.
|