1.1 WHAT IS REGIONAL ECONOMICS?
Economic systems
are dynamic entities, and the nature and consequences of changes that take
place in these systems are of considerable importance. Such change affects the
well-being of individuals and ultimately the social and political fabric of
community and nation. As social beings, we cannot help but react to the changes
we observe. For some people that reaction is quite passive; the economy
changes, and they find that their immediate environment is somehow different,
forcing adjustment to the new reality. For others, changes in the economic
system represent a challenge; they seek to understand the nature of factors
that have led to change and may, in light of that knowledge, adjust their own
patterns of behavior or attempt to bring about change in the economic,
political, and social systems in which they live and work.
In this context,
regional economics represents a framework within which the spatial character of economic systems may be understood. We seek to identify the
factors governing the distribution of economic activity over space and to
recognize that as this distribution changes, there will be important
consequences for individuals and for communities.
Thus, regional or
"spatial" economics might be summed up in the question "What is where, and
whyand so what?" The first what refers to every type of economic
activity: not only production establishments in the narrow sense of factories,
farms, and mines, but also other kinds of businesses, households, and private
and public institutions. Where refers to location in relation to other
economic activity; it involves questions of proximity, concentration,
dispersion, and similarity or disparity of spatial patterns, and it can be
discussed either in broad terms, such as among regions, or microgeographically,
in terms of zones, neighborhoods, and sites. The why and the so what refer to interpretations within the somewhat elastic limits of the
economist's competence and daring.
Regional economics
is a relatively young branch of economics. Its late start exemplifies the
regrettable tendency of formal professional disciplines to lose contact with
one another and to neglect some important problem areas that require a mixture
of approaches. Until fairly recently, traditional economists ignored the where question altogether, finding plenty of problems to occupy them
without giving any spatial dimension to their analysis. Traditional
geographers, though directly concerned with what is where, lacked any
real technique of explanation in terms of human behavior and institutions to
supply the why, and resorted to mere description and mapping.
Traditional city planners, similarly limited, remained preoccupied with the
physical and aesthetic aspects of idealized urban layouts.
This unfortunate
situation has been corrected to a remarkable extent within the last few
decades. Individuals who call themselves by various professional
labelseconomists, geographers, ecologists, city and regional planners,
regional scientists, and urbanistshave joined to develop analytical tools
and skills, and to apply them to some of the most pressing problems of the
time.
The unflagging
pioneer work and the intellectual and organizational leadership of Walter Isard
since the 1940s played a key role in enlisting support from various disciplines
to create this new focus. His domain of "regional science" is extremely broad.
This book will follow a less comprehensive approach, using the special
interests and capabilities of the economist as a point of departure.
1.2 THREE
FOUNDATION STONES
It will be helpful
to realize at the outset that three fundamental considerations underlie the
complex patterns of location of economic activity and most of the major
problems of regional economics.
The first of these
"foundation stones" appears in the simplistic explanations of the location of
industries and cities that can still be found in old-style geography books.
Wine and movies are made in California because there is plenty of sunshine
there; New York and New Orleans are great port cities because each has a
natural water-level route to the interior of the country; easily developable
waterpower sites located the early mill towns of New England; and so on. In
other words, the unequal distribution of climate, minerals, soil, topography,
and most other natural features helps to explain the location of many kinds of
economic activity. A bit more generally and in the more precise terminology of
economic theory, we can identify the complete or partial immobility of land
and other productive factors as one essential part of any explanation of
what is where. Such immobility lies at the heart of the comparative
advantage that various regions enjoy for specialization in production and
trade.
This is, however,
by no means an adequate explanation. One of the pioneers of regional economics,
August Lösch, set himself the question of what kind of location patterns
might logically be expected to appear in an imaginary world in which all
natural resource differentials were assumed away, that is, in a uniformly
endowed flat plain.1 In such a situation, one
might conceivably expect (1) concentration of all activities at one spot, (2)
uniform dispersion of all activities over the entire area (that is, perfect
homogeneity), or (3) no systematic pattern at all, but a random scatter of
activities. What does actually appear as the logical outcome is none of these,
but an elaborate and interesting regular pattern somewhat akin to various
crystal structures and showing some recognizable similarity to real-world
patterns of distribution of cities and towns. We shall have a look at this
pattern in Chapter 8. What the
Christaller-Lösch theoretical exercises demonstrated was that factors
other than natural-resource location play an important part in explaining the
spatial pattern of activities.
In developing his
abstract model, Lösch assumed just two economic constraints determining
location: (1) economies of spatial concentration and (2) transport costs. These
are the second and third essential foundation stones.
Economists have
long been aware of the importance of economies of scale, particularly since the
days of Adam Smith, and have analyzed them largely in terms of imperfect
divisibility of production factors and other goods and services. The
economies of spatial concentration in their turn can, as we shall see in Chapter 5 and elsewhere, be traced mainly to
economies of scale in specific industries.
Finally, goods and
services are not freely or instantaneously mobile: Transport and communication
cost something in effort and time. These costs limit the extent to which
advantages of natural endowment or economies of spatial concentration can be
realized.
To sum up, an
understanding of spatial and regional economic problems can be built on three
facts of life: (1) natural-resource advantages, (2) economies of concentration,
and (3) costs of transport and communication. In more technical language, these
foundation stones can be identified as (1) imperfect factor mobility, (2)
imperfect divisibility, and (3) imperfect mobility of goods and
services.
1.3 REGIONAL
ECONOMIC PROBLEMS AND THE PLAN OF THIS BOOK
What, then, are the
actual problems in which an understanding of spatial economics can be helpful?
They arise, as we shall see, on several different levels. Some are primarily
microeconomic, involving the spatial preferences, decisions, and experiences of
such units as households or business firms. Others involve the behavior of
large groups of people, whole industries, or such areas as cities or regions.
To give some idea of the range of questions involved and also the approach that
this book takes in developing a conceptual framework to handle them, we shall
follow here a sequence corresponding to the successive later chapters.
The business firm
is, of course, most directly interested in what regional economics may have to
say about choosing a profitable location in relation to given markets, sources
of materials, labor, services, and other relevant location factors. A
nonbusiness unit such as a household, institution, or public facility faces an
analogous problem of location choice, though the specific location factors to
be considered may be rather different and less subject to evaluation in terms
of price and profit. Our survey of regional economics begins in Chapter 2 by taking a microeconomic viewpoint.
That is, all locations, conditions, and activities other than the individual
unit in question will be taken as given: The individual unit's problem is to
decide what location it prefers.
The importance of
transport and communication services in determining locations (one of the three
foundation stones) will become evident in Chapter 2. The relation of distance
to the cost of the spatial movement of goods and services, however, is not
simple. It depends on such factors as route layouts, scale economies in
terminal and carriage operations, the length of the journey, the
characteristics of the goods and services transferred, and the technical
capabilities of the available transport and communication media. Chapter 3 identifies and explains such relations
and will explore their effects on the advantages of different
locations.
In Chapter 4, an analysis of pricing decisions and
demand in a spatial context is developed. This analysis extends some principles
of economics concerning the theory of pricing and output decisions to the
spatial dimension. As a result, we shall be able to appreciate more fully the
relationship between pricing policies and the market area of a seller. We shall
find also that space provides yet another dimension for competition among
sellers. Further, this analysis will serve as a basis for understanding the
location patterns of whole industries. If an individual firm or
other unit has any but the most myopic outlook, it will want to know something
about shifts in such patterns. For example, a firm producing oil-drilling or
refinery equipment should be interested in the locational shifts in the oil
industry and a business firm enjoying favorable access to a market should want
to know whether it is likely that more competition will be coming its
way.
While some of the
issues developed in Chapter 4 concern factors that contribute to the dispersion
of sellers within an industry, Chapter 5 recognizes the powerful forces that may draw sellers together in space. From an
analysis of various types of economies of spatial concentration and a
description of empirical evidence bearing on their significance, we shall find
that the nature of this foundation stone of location decisions can have
important consequences for local areas or regions.
Chapter 6 introduces explicit recognition of the fact
that activities require space. Space (or distance, which is simply space in one
dimension) plays an interestingly dual role in the location of activities. On
the one hand, distance represents cost and inconvenience when there is a need
for access (for instance, in commuting to work or delivering a product to the
market), and transport and communication represent more or less costly ways of
surmounting the handicaps to human interaction imposed by distance. But at the
same time, every human activity requires space for itself. In intensively
developed areas, sheer elbowroom as well as the amenities of privacy are scarce
and valuable. In this context, space and distance appear as assets rather than
as liabilities.
Chapter 6 treats
competition for space as a factor helping to determine location patterns and
individual choices. The focus here is still more "macro" than the discussion of
location patterns developed in preceding chapters, in that it is concerned with
the spatial ordering of different types of land use around some special
pointfor example, zones of different kinds of agriculture around a market
center. In Chapter 6, the location patterns of many industries or other
activities are considered as constituents of the land-use pattern of an area,
like pieces of a jigsaw puzzle. Many of the real problems with which regional
economies deal are in fact posed in terms of land use (How is this site or area
best used?) rather than in terms of location per se (Where is this firm,
household, or industry best situated?). The insights developed in this chapter
are relevant, then, not only for the individual locators but also for those
owning land, operating transit or other utility services, or otherwise having a
stake in what happens to a given piece of territory.
The land-use
analysis of Chapter 6 serves also as a basis for understanding the spatial
organization of economic activity within urban areas. For this reason, Chapter 7 employs the principles of resource
allocation that govern land use and exposes the fundamental spatial structure
of urban areas. Consideration is given also to the reasons for and implications
of changes in urban spatial structure. This analysis provides a framework for
understanding a diverse array of problems faced by city planners and community
developers and redevelopers.
In Chapter 8, the focus is broadened once more in
order to understand patterns of urbanization within a region: the spacing,
sizes, and functions of cities, and particularly the relationship between size
and function. Real-world questions involving this so-called central-place
analysis include, for example, trends in city-size distributions. Is the
crossroads hamlet or the small town losing its functions and becoming obsolete,
or is its place in the spatial order becoming more important? What size city or
town is the best location for some specific kind of business or public
facility? What services and facilities are available only in middle-sized and
larger cities, or only in the largest metropolitan centers? In the planned
developed or underdeveloped region, what size distribution and location pattern
of cities would be most appropriate? Any principles or insights that can help
answer such questions or expose the nature of their complexity are obviously
useful to a wide range of individuals.
Chapter
9 deals with regions of various types in terms of their structure and
functions. In particular, it concerns the internal economic ties or "linkages"
among activities and interests that give a region organic entity and make it a
useful unit for description, analysis, administration, planning, and
policy.
After an understanding of the
nature of regions is developed in Chapter 9, our attention turns to growth and
change and to the usefulness and desirability of locational changes, as
distinct from rationalizations of observed behavior or patterns.
Chapter 10 deals specifically with people and
their personal locational preferences; it is a necessary prelude to the
consideration of regional and urban development and policy that follows.
Migration is the central topic, since people most clearly express their
locational likes and dislikes by moving. Some insight into the factors that
determine who moves where, and when, is needed by anyone trying to foresee
population changes (such as regional and community planners and developers,
utility companies, and the like). This insight is even more important in
connection with framing public policies aimed at relieving regional or local
poverty and unemployment.
Chapters 11 and 12, dealing with regional development and related
policy issues, are concerned wit the region as a whole plus a still higher
level of concern; namely, the national interest in the welfare and growth of
the nation's constituent regions. Chapter 11, building on the concepts of
regional structure developed in Chapter 9, concentrates on the process and
causes of regional growth and change. Viewing the region as a live organism, we
develop a basic understanding of its anatomy and physiology. Chapter 12
proposes appropriate objectives for regional development (involving, that is,
the definition of regional economic "health"). It analyzes the economic ills to
which regions are heir (pathology) and ventures to assess the merits of various
kinds of policy to help distressed regions (therapeutics).
Throughout this text, evidence of
the special significance of the "urban" region will be found. Discussions of
economies associated with the spatial concentration of activity, land use, and
regional development and policy have important urban dimensions. It is fitting,
the, that the last chapter of the text, Chapter
13, focuses on some major present-day urban problems and possible curative
or palliative measures. Attention is given to four areas of concern (downtown
blight, poverty, urban transport, and urban fiscal distress) in which spatial
economic relationships are particularly important and the relevance of our
specialized approach is therefore strong.
It is hoped that this discussion
has served to create an awareness of some basic factors governing the spatial
distribution of economic activity and their importance in a larger setting. The
course of study on which we are about to embark will introduce a framework for
understanding the mechanisms by which these factors have effect. It holds out
the prospect of developing perspective on associated problems and a basis for
the analysis of those problems and their consequences.
SELECTED
READINGS
Martin Beckmann, Location
Theory (New York: Random House, 1968).
Edgar M. Hoover, "Spatial
Economics: Partial Equilibrium Approach," in Encyclopedia of the Social
Sciences (New York: Macmillan, 1968).
Walter Isard, Location and
Space-Economy (Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, 1956).
August Lösch, Die
räumliche Ordnung der Wirtschaft (Jena: Gustav Fischer, 1940;
2nd ed., 1944); W. H. Woglom (tr.), The Economics of Location (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1954).
Leon Moses, "Spatial Economics:
General Equilibrium Approach," in Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences (New York: Macmillan, 1968).
Hugh O. Nourse, Regional
Economics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1968).
Harry W. Richardson, "The State of
Regional Economics," International Regional Science Review, 3, 1 (Fall
1978), 1-48.
Harry W. Richardson, Regional
Economics (Urbana, Ill.: University of Illinois Press, 1979).
ENDNOTES
1. A point of
departure for Lösch's work was that of a predecessor, the geographer
Walter Christaller, whose studies were more empirically oriented.